Bryan Caplan's Blog, page 85

March 6, 2017

Soonish by Kelly and Zach Weinersmith, by Bryan Caplan

soonish.jpg My co-author, Zach Weinersmith, and his wife, Kelly Weinersmith, have a new book out on future technology and its economic and social implications.  News flash: Soonish is currently at #3 on Amazon.  As Neo said, "Woh."

(0 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on March 06, 2017 15:50

San Diego Immigration Debate, by Bryan Caplan

On March 16, I'm debating at the University of San Diego on, "Is Immigration a Basic Human Right?" My opponent is philosopher Christopher "Kit" Wellman of Washington University.  His work on the subject is frankly puzzling, since to my mind he concedes every premise I need to make the case for open borders, with several back-up premises to spare.  But we shall see...

P.S. I may be able to run an RPG in San Diego while I'm in town.  If you're interested, email me.

(5 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on March 06, 2017 10:25

March 2, 2017

Power-Hunger, by Bryan Caplan

"Greed is good."  After a few years in economics, the goodness of greed seems like common sense.  But it's not.  In a randomly selected social environment, greed is brutal.  If you're carrying a bag of gold and meet a well-armed stranger in a remote jungle, you wouldn't say, "As long as he's greedy, I have nothing to worry about."  The knowledge that Nigerian spammers are greedy doesn't incline you to send them your money.  If you were looking for a caretaker for your elderly mother, discovering that a job candidate is "extremely greedy" would be a strong mark against him.  As Marge Gunderson sadly muses at the end of Fargo , "So that was Mrs. Lundegaard on the floor in there. And I guess that was
your accomplice in the wood chipper. And those three people in Brainerd.
And for what? For a little bit of money. There's more to life than a
little money, you know. Don't you know that?"

What economics teaches is not that greed is good, but that good incentives transform this questionable motive into awesome results.  Greed plus property rights plus competition plus rationality plus reputation is good.  Greed alone is film noir.

In Public Choice, also known as "economics of politics," we usually assume that politicians are motivated not by greed, but by power-hunger.  Of course, we rarely utter the word "power-hunger."  Instead, we call it "vote maximization," just as we call greed "profit maximization."  But when Public Choice pictures politicians, it pictures humans filled with lust for power.

Is this a reasonable picture of politicians' psyches?  Absolutely.  That politicians crave power is as undeniable as that businesspeople crave profits.  If you look at political history before the rise of democracy, we see virtually nothing other than dictators struggling to cement their power internally and expand their power externally.  When these dictators lost wars, they lost territory and subjects, because virtually every dictators wanted to rule over as much land and as many people as possible. 

Under democracy, politicians are less candid about their motives; they need us to like them, and power-hunger is not likeable.  But given its ubiquity throughout most of political history, can we really believe that the motive of power-hunger is no longer paramount?  One of my favorite political insiders privately calls politicians of both parties "psychopaths" - and he's on to something.  Rising high on the pyramid of power is hard unless love of power fuels your ascent.

In a randomly-selected social environment, power-hunger - like greed - is brutal.  Just look at the history of warfare in all its hideousness - the endless bloodbaths over slivers of territory.  Remember how leaders terrorized their rivals, their potential rivals, their imagined rivals.  It's sickening.  If Fargo were a war story, and Marge Gunderson hunted war criminals, she might have sadly mused, "So that was Sarajevo on the floor in there. And I guess those were
your accomplices in the mass grave. And those three hundred thousand people in Bosnia.
And for what? For a little bit of power. There's more to life than a
little power, you know. Don't you know that?"

In dictatorships, the causal chain from power-hunger to bad results is obvious.  The fundamental question of Public Choice is: Does democracy motivate power-hungry politicians to do good despite their bad intentions?  My admirable nemesis, Donald Wittman, tirelessly argues Yes, but to no avail.  Democracy out-performs dictatorship, but that's damning with faint praise. 

Once you thank the stars you aren't ruled by Louis XIV or Lenin, a grim truth remains: democracy gives power-hungry politicians far worse incentives than the market gives greedy businesspeople.  Above all, voters - unlike consumers - have no incentive to be rational, spurring power-hungry politicians to preach and practice endless demagoguery.  It's gotten worse lately, but it's always been terrible.  Democracy hasn't turned politicians into decent human beings; it's only gilded their age-old power lust with altruistic hypocrisy.

So what can we do about our predicament?  There are no easy answers, but I know where to start.  Like alcoholics, we must admit we have a problem.  Throughout history and around the world, the wicked rule.  We should stop admiring them - especially the politicians on "our side" - and see them for the reprobates they are.

(8 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on March 02, 2017 10:51

March 1, 2017

Read Meer, by Bryan Caplan

meer.jpgToday's speaker at the Public Choice Seminar is Jonathan Meer of Texas A&M, one of my favorite young empirical economists in the world. He's doing the most innovative work on the minimum wage, wisely building on the ubiquity of firing aversion.  He's also doing creative and multi-pronged work on education, charity, labor, and health economics.  All his research is conveniently accessible right here.  Enjoy!


(1 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on March 01, 2017 06:52

February 28, 2017

My Deportation Index: The Drum Critique, by Bryan Caplan

Kevin Drum thoughtfully critiques my Deportation Index.  But first, he makes my numbers look pretty:

drum.jpg

His critique begins with some some data I didn't know about.
The next step is to calculate this as a percentage of the number of illegal immigrants in the country each year. Here it is:

drum2.jpgHis punchline:
This is approximate, since the total population of illegal immigrants is
a little fuzzy before 2000. But it's close enough. Obama still has a
higher removal rate and a lower index rate than any other president, but
the winner for the title of Deporter-in-Chief is...Ronald Reagan. Every
president since then has been successively more tolerant of a large
undocumented population.
It's a thought-provoking point.  For the typical immigrant, justified fear of deportation peaked under Reagan, then almost continuously declined.  But when we're playing Lord Acton ("Suffer no man and no cause to escape the undying penalty which history
has the power to inflict on wrong"), does it make sense to adjust for the population of potential victims?  Or should we just count the victims?  I honestly don't know.

(7 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on February 28, 2017 07:45

February 27, 2017

Trump Bet Clarification, by Bryan Caplan

In November, I bet an anonymous EconLog reader:
If Donald
Trump resigns, is removed  by the Senate after impeachment, or otherwise
is permanently removed as per the the 25th Amendment, or if it never happens
that he takes the Oath of office as POTUS on Jan 20, 2017, the BC owes [redacted] $350.
Otherwise, [redacted] owes BC $100".
When re-reading the bet, however, I realized that I omitted a key understanding of the bet.  After consulting with my partner, we've amended the terms to reflect our original intent.  It now reads:
If Donald
Trump dies in office, resigns, is removed  by the Senate after impeachment, or otherwise
is permanently removed as per the the 25th Amendment, or if it never happens
that he takes the Oath of office as POTUS on Jan 20, 2017, the BC owes [redacted] $350.
Otherwise, [redacted] owes BC $100".
Note that this revision is entirely adverse to my interests.  In fact, as I said before, I think Trump's death is my most probable losing scenario.

(1 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on February 27, 2017 08:16

February 23, 2017

Who's the Real "Deporter in Chief"?, by Bryan Caplan

Immigration activists repeated named Obama the "Deporter in Chief."  Were they right?  Strictly speaking, yes: More human beings were deported under Obama than any other presidency in history.  Substantively, however, the critics were very wrong.  Key fact: U.S. immigration law - and U.S. immigration statistics - makes a big distinction between full-blown deportations ("Removals") and "voluntarily" returning home under the threat of full-blown deportation ("Returns"). 

The distinction is not entirely cosmetic.  If you re-enter after Removal, you face a serious risk of federal jail time if you're caught.  If you re-enter after a mere Return, you generally don't.  But Return is still almost as bad as Removal, since both exile you from the country where you prefer to reside.  Since I've previously suggested that we should count each Return as 85% of a Removal, I've constructed a "Deportation Index" equal to Removals + .85*Returns to capture the substance of U.S. immigration policy.  Check out the numbers:







Year
Removals
Returns
Deportation Index


1977
31,263
867,015
768,226


1978
29,277
975,515
858,465


1979
26,825
966,137
848,041


1980
18,013
719,211
629,342


1981
17,379
823,875
717,673


1982
15,216
812,572
705,902


1983
19,211
931,600
811,071


1984
18,696
909,833
792,054


1985
23,105
1,041,296
908,207


1986
24,592
1,586,320
1,372,964


1987
24,336
1,091,203
951,859


1988
25,829
911,790
800,851


1989
34,427
830,890
740,684


1990
30,039
1,022,533
899,192


1991
33,189
1,061,105
935,128


1992
43,671
1,105,829
983,626


1993
42,542
1,243,410
1,099,441


1994
45,674
1,029,107
920,415


1995
50,924
1,313,764
1,167,623


1996
69,680
1,573,428
1,407,094


1997
114,432
1,440,684
1,339,013


1998
174,813
1,570,127
1,509,421


1999
183,114
1,574,863
1,521,748


2000
188,467
1,675,876
1,612,962


2001
189,026
1,349,371
1,335,991


2002
165,168
1,012,116
1,025,467


2003
211,098
945,294
1,014,598


2004
240,665
1,166,576
1,232,255


2005
246,431
1,096,920
1,178,813


2006
280,974
1,043,381
1,167,848


2007
319,382
891,390
1,077,064


2008
359,795
811,263
1,049,369


2009
391,341
582,596
886,548


2010
381,738
474,195
784,804


2011
386,020
322,098
659,803


2012
416,324
230,360
612,130


2013
434,015
178,691
585,902


2014
407,075
163,245
545,833


2015
333,341
129,122
443,095


Notice: Despite the rise in Removals under Obama, Returns crashed.  Obama's Deportation Index therefore falls as soon as he takes office - and then declines further every single year!  By 2015, Obama's D.I. is half its 2009 value, and about one-third of its previous peak under Bush II.

Does this mean Democrats are the genuine friend of the immigrant?  Not exactly.  Here are the average D.I.s for every president from Carter to Obama.  The last column adjusts for population in millions, which, as you can see, makes the pattern even more extreme.



President
Average D.I.
Average D.I./Pop/10^6


Carter
776,019
3,471


Reagan
882,572
3,718


Bush I
889,657
3,534


Clinton
1,322,215
4,861


Bush II
1,135,175
3,861


Obama
645,445
2,068



Yes, while Obama has the lowest D.I. of any president over the last four decades, the real Deporter in Chief was none other than fellow Democrat Bill Clinton. Adjusting for population, no one else even comes close.  Indeed, while I'm very confident that Trump's D.I. will exceed Obama's, it's far from clear that Trump will manage to displace Clinton from the top spot.  (Betting odds: I'll give 4:1 that Trump's average D.I. when he leaves office will exceed Obama's, but only even money than he'll exceed Clinton's).

The lesson, as usual, is that we should look past surface rhetoric to the bedrock of numbers.  While both Democrats and Republicans casually equate Clinton and Obama, their immigration policies were as different as day and night.

(4 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on February 23, 2017 10:55

February 22, 2017

Do Middle-Class College Kids Already Have a UBI?, by Bryan Caplan

In our Universal Basic Income debate, Will Wilkinson had one fun argument I didn't have time to answer.  His claim: Middle-class college kids (like stereotypical Students for Liberty attendees) already get a UBI from their parents.  Thanks to this UBI, Will argued, middle-class kids have the buffer they need to explore their interests and hone their skills - and the disincentive effects are barely noticeable.  Wouldn't it be great if everyone enjoyed the same privilege at taxpayer expense?

My reply: While middle-class parents do commonly provide ample financial support for their children, it's nothing like a UBI.  Instead, it's heavily means-tested: We'll keep supporting you as long as you pursue a responsible path.  "Either stay in school and get passing grades, or get a job and pay rent" is perhaps the typical deal.  Many parents add further micromanagement: To receive support, you need high grades, a realistic major, sobriety, and a suitable boyfriend.  Only a minority agree to let their children live as they please at their parents' expense.  When they do, the results seem pretty bleak.  I know of no systematic data on never-employed single 30-year-olds living in their parents' basements, but the anecdotal evidence is chilling.  Even parents who provide "unconditional" support ultimately tend to lose patience and angrily switch to old-school "sink-or-swim."  And who could blame them?

Will might decry this as "paternalism," but a subtler analysis is in order.  For starters, the heart of paternalism is treating adults like children.  But parents' obvious reply is, "We're treating our kids like children because they're acting like children."  Until you are self-supporting, demanding full autonomy is just chutzpah.  In any case, pure self-interest also urges us to impose conditions on our dependents' behavior.  "If you want to sleep on my couch, you'd better get to your job interview on time" need not be motivated by my desire to give you a "happy life full of hard work."  Maybe I just want my couch back.

To circle back to my broader theme, if people who love you have good reason to impose conditions on their voluntary assistance, people who've never even met you have overwhelming reason to impose conditions on their involuntary assistance.  And involuntary assistance is the heart of the welfare state. 

(8 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on February 22, 2017 11:05

February 21, 2017

UBI Debate Video, by Bryan Caplan

Video of the Wilkinson-Caplan Universal Basic Income Debate is available here.  The video quality could be a little higher, but the camera does get properly rotated after a few seconds.  Thanks again to Students for Liberty and the Institute for Humane Studies for setting it all up!

(0 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on February 21, 2017 07:30

February 20, 2017

Why Libertarians Should Oppose the Universal Basic Income, by Bryan Caplan

Here's my opening statement for my Students for Liberty debate with Will Wilkinson.  Enjoy.



Libertarians
have a standard set of fundamental criticisms of the welfare state. 



1. Forced
charity is unjust.  Individuals have a
moral right to decide if and when they want to help others.



2. Forced
charity is unnecessary.  In a free
market, voluntary donations are enough to provide for the truly poor.



3. Forced
charity gives recipients bad incentives. 
If the government takes care of you, you're less likely to take care of
yourself by work and saving.



4. The cost
of forced charity is high and growing rapidly, leading to a future of exhorbitant
taxes or financial crisis.



 



Taken
together, I think these criticisms justify the radical libertarian view that
the welfare state should be abolished.   But this is an extremely unpopular view, so it's
natural for libertarians to consider more moderate reforms like the Universal
Basic Income.  And when you're
considering moderate reforms, the right question to ask isn't: "Is it ideal?"
but "Is it better than the status quo?" 



My claim:
the Universal Basic Income is indeed worse than the status quo.  In fact, all the fundamental criticisms of
the welfare state apply with even greater force.



1. Some
forced charity is more unjust than other forced charity.  Forcing people to help others who can't help themselves - like kids from
poor families or the severely disabled - is at least defensible.  Forcing people to help everyone is not.  And for all
its faults, at least the status quo makes some
effort to target people who can't help themselves.  The whole idea of the Universal Basic Income,
in contrast, is of course to give money to everyone whether they need it or
not.  Of course, the UBI formula normally
reduces the net payment as income rises; but if a perfectly able-bodied person
chooses never to work, the UBI gravy train never stops.



2. The UBI is
an extremely wasteful form of forced charity. 
Helping the small minority of people who can't help themselves doesn't
cost much.  Giving an unconditional grant
to every citizen wastes an enormous amount of money.  If you were running a private charity, it
would never even occur to you to "help everyone," because it's such a frivolous
use of scarce charitable resources. 
Instead, you'd target spending to do the most good.  And unlike the UBI, the status quo makes some effort to so target its resources.



3. Overall,
the UBI probably gives even worse
incentives than the status quo.  Defenders
of the UBI correctly point out that it might improve incentives for people who
are already on welfare.  Under the status quo, earning another $1 of
legal income can easily reduce your welfare by a $1, implying a marginal tax
rate of 100%.  But under the status quo,
vast populations are ineligible for most programs.  Such as? 
You guys!  If you're an
able-bodied adult, aged 18-64, who doesn't have custody of any minor children, the
current system doesn't give you much. 
Switching to a UBI would expand the familiar perverse effects of the
welfare state to the entire population - including you.  And if taxes rise to pay for the UBI, the population-wide
disincentives are even worse.



4. A
politically acceptable UBI would be insanely expensive.  Libertarian economist and UBI advocate Ed
Dolan has a detailed, fiscally viable plan to provide a UBI of $4452 per person
per year.  But every non-libertarian I've
queried thinks it should be at least $10,000 per person per year.  Even with a one-third flat tax, that implies
that a family of four would have to make $120,000 a year before it paid $1 of
taxes.  This is pie in the sky.



But doesn't
the UBI give people their freedom?  In
some socialist sense, sure.  But
libertarianism isn't about the freedom to be coercively supported by strangers.  It's about the freedom to be left alone by
strangers.



If abolition
of the welfare state is extremely unlikely and the UBI is worse than the status
quo, does this mean libertarians should accept the welfare state as it is?  Not at all. 
There's a straightforward moderate path to a freer world: AUSTERITY.  Cut benefits. 
Restrict eligibility.  Remind the
world of the great Forgotten Man: the taxpayer. 
We probably can't convince the majority to end the welfare state.  But "Welfare should be limited to genuinely
poor people who can't help themselves" has broad appeal - and unlike the UBI, it's
a clear step in the libertarian direction.

(12 COMMENTS)
 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on February 20, 2017 11:05

Bryan Caplan's Blog

Bryan Caplan
Bryan Caplan isn't a Goodreads Author (yet), but they do have a blog, so here are some recent posts imported from their feed.
Follow Bryan Caplan's blog with rss.