Aaron E. Carroll's Blog, page 141
March 20, 2017
The Cost Can Be Debated, but Meals on Wheels Gets Results
The following originally appeared on The Upshot (copyright 2017, The New York Times Company).
Meals on Wheels has been delivering food to older people in the United States since the 1950s. Last year it served 2.4 million people. This week, after President Trump released his budget proposal, a furor erupted over the program’s future and effectiveness. Let’s look at the evidence.
Mr. Trump’s budget proposes big cuts to discretionary spending. In a news conference on Thursday, his budget director, Mick Mulvaney, defended cuts to the Community Development Block Grant program by arguing that it was “just not showing any results.” (Some states give a portion of that block grant money to Meals on Wheels.)
“We can’t spend money on programs just because they sound good,” Mr. Mulvaney said. “And Meals on Wheels sounds great — again, that’s a state decision to fund that particular portion to. But to take the federal money and give it to the states and say, ‘Look, we want to give you money for programs that don’t work’ — I can’t defend that anymore.”
Despite expressions of alarm on social media, killing the community block grant program would most likely not kill Meals on Wheels. The financial statements from 2015 show that such grants amounted to just under $250,000, or about 3 percent of the total revenue for the program’s national resource center. More than 85 percent came from corporate, foundation and personal donations. Clearly, federal funding for the national program office isn’t the linchpin for its success.
Public funds at the local level, however, are more substantial, and Meals on Wheels gets much more funding through a different federal program. The nutrition programs of the Older Americans Act support the Meals on Wheels chapters as they actually operate on the ground, and about 30 percent of the expense of home-delivered meals is covered by federal sources.
A cut to this program would have a far more significant effect, especially since that support had been decreasing even before the new budget was considered. The Trump budget calls for a 17.9 percent cut in funding for this program’s parent agency, the Department of Health and Human Services, and it is quite possible Meals on Wheels could be affected. We won’t know until H.H.S. finalizes its budget.
Now, what about the assumption, explicit or implicit, that the program has not achieved “results”?
Meals on Wheels has been the subject of many peer-reviewed studies in the medical literature. So many have been done that there are several systematic reviews gathering these studies into various domains.
In 2014, researchers explored the evidence on whether home-delivered meal programs improved the diet and nutrition of older Americans. They found eight studies, two of which were randomized controlled trials. Six of the eight showed that programs like Meals on Wheels improve the quality of people’s diet, increase their nutrient intake, and reduce their food insecurity and nutritional risk. They also noted that the programs increased chances for human contact and improved quality of life.
A 2015 review found that 80 studies have been conducted on programs like Meals on Wheels. The authors noted, however, that few of these were randomized controlled trials, and that even fewer focused on the program as a whole. They were correct, and I am sympathetic to these calls for more rigorous trials. But such trials are hard to do, they’re expensive, and funding for them seems to be going down, not up.
Saying that you want better evidence is different from saying that there is no evidence, though.
It’s important to recognize that the program’s benefits are not merely nutritional. A 2016 study showed that participants in the Meals on Wheels program had lower loneliness scores. A 2013 study showed that spending on services like Meals on Wheels was associated with less reliance on institutionalized care, because more people could live independently at home. They may even have fewer falls at home and less worry about being able to remain there.
Finally, although no one measures it, Meals on Wheels brings people food they otherwise wouldn’t have.
Researchers conducted economic analyses in 2013 and showed that if all states had increased the number of older Americans who had received Meals on Wheels by just 1 percent, the states would have saved Medicaid more than $109 million. Most of those savings would have come from reductions in the need for nursing home care.
We can debate the cost-effectiveness of Meals on Wheels, but it would be wrong to say that it’s not effective. There are plenty of results, and I’ve highlighted only some of the most rigorous research available. Most programs we fund through tax dollars have far less evidence to support them, if any evidence at all.
About the worst thing you might say about Meals on Wheels is that putting money into a different program might be of more help to older Americans. There’s no evidence that Meals on Wheels is the most cost-effective program there is, or that it’s the most efficient use of our taxpayer dollars.
Any argument that goes in that direction, though, raises the question of whether there is a program that does a better job, and whether there is evidence to support it.
March 17, 2017
AcademyHealth: Explaining the growth in Medicare Advantage
Medicare Advantage’s cost to Medicare is different than traditional Medicare’s. So, predicting MA enrollment is important for projecting future Medicare costs to taxpayers. We’ve entered an era in which such prediction has become difficult and more speculative. In my latest AcademyHealth post I get some help from colleagues in trying to explain MA’s enrollment growth.
Healthcare Triage: Results Are In! Congressional Budget Office Scores the American Health Care Act
Want to know what’s in the CBO report? Don’t want to read it? We’ve got you covered. Another very special episode of Healthcare Triage:
Text of the report here.
Out of Sight, Out of Mind — Behavioral and Developmental Care for Rural Children
Today in the NEJM, Kelly Kelleher (of Nationwide Children’s Hospital) and I discuss rural US kids with mental health and developmental disorders, and the obstacles to caring for them.
We summarize new data from the Centers for Disease Control about the epidemiology of these problems among rural kids. We also discuss data from the US Department of Agriculture which show that poverty is higher among rural children than urban children and that rural child poverty is higher than it has been since 1993.

Poverty is more common for rural children.
Then we look at the many obstacles to getting services to kids in rural settings, particularly the lack of mental health specialists. It’s a problem in the US and Canada, both of which have large regions with low population densities.
We conclude:
A romantic and pastoral view of the countryside as a place of healing is ingrained in American culture. The increased burden of MBDDs among rural children belies this image, as does the failure of the traditional behavioral and developmental health care system to address rural children’s needs. These problems have received too little attention, because most behavioral and developmental health specialists, researchers, and health policymakers live in cities. The problems of rural children, their families’ crises, and the lack of services have been out of sight and out of mind.
And of course I have to say: please read the whole thing!
Our article was in press before the text of the AHCA was released. Sara Rosenbaum reports that the bill changes Medicaid in several ways.
the House bill essentially eliminates the enhanced funding levels that made possible states’ expansion of Medicaid to their poorest working-age adult residents, something that 31 states and the District of Columbia now have done. Expansion states could face up to a 40-point difference between the federal funding enhancements they expected to receive in 2020 for the expansion population and what they actually would receive under the bill. What is at stake is continued coverage for some 11 million of the more than 16 million people who have gained eligibility since full implementation of the ACA Medicaid expansion.
The proposed changes could harm rural America, and rural American kids specifically, in two ways.
First, many rural families are covered by Medicaid. Losing this coverage will increase the stress on already highly-stressed families. Medicaid funding is also critical to the children’s hospitals that are among the primary places that kids get care for developmental and mental health disorders.
Second, rural Americans are currently experiencing a significant public health crisis involving opiates, amphetamines, and suicide. Parental substance abuse can adversely affect children. The AHCA has a provision that may undermine efforts to address the substance abuse epidemic. Katie Zezima and Chris Ingraham report in the Washington Post that
Beginning in 2020, the plan would eliminate an Affordable Care Act requirement that Medicaid cover basic mental-health and addiction services in states that expanded it, allowing them to decide whether to include those benefits in Medicaid plans.
There are large areas in rural Americas where there are no addiction services. If Medicaid funding shrinks, state administrators will look for places to cut. Eliminating the requirement to fund mental health and addiction services means that funding shortfalls will disproportionately affect kids with mental health and developmental disorders.
March 16, 2017
Performance art: Trump proposes a 20% cut to the NIH
From Science, Donald Trump’s first budget for research:
President Donald Trump’s first budget request to Congress, to be released at 7 a.m. Thursday, will call for cutting the 2018 budget of the National Institutes of Health (NIH) by $6 billion, or nearly 20%, according to sources familiar with the proposal. The Department of Energy’s (DOE’s) Office of Science would lose $900 million, or nearly 20% of its $5 billion budget. The proposal also calls for deep cuts to the research programs at the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) and the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA), and a 5% cut to NASA’s Earth science budget. And it would eliminate DOE’s roughly $300 million Advanced Research Projects Agency – Energy (ARPA-E).
This is absurd. The US Congress hasn’t passed a budget since 2009, but if by some miracle it does in 2017, it will not include a 20% decrease in the NIH budget. Does the President understand that the Congress will not do this? Does he even know that his budget says this?

Rotten, J., et al. (1979)
Well, someone in his office wrote these numbers down. What point was that person trying to make? Consider the budget not as a plan for governing but as an artistic performance, a kind of Sex Pistols track from the alt-right, a scream of anger against the dull conformity of funding research into health and well-being.
What values are being expressed?
Cardiovascular diseases doesn’t matter? (CDC: 610,000 people die of heart disease in the United States every year.)
Cancer doesn’t matter? (CDC: 595,000 people die of cancer in the United States every year.)
Substance abuse doesn’t matter? (CDC: 50,000 opioid-involved deaths in the United States every year.)
Nothing matters?
What does the administration value? The US government spends $3 million on each weekend Trump spends in Palm Beach. That will come to $130 million per year at the current pace. An average NIH R01 grant costs $500K. The President’s weekly resort trips cost us 260 medical research projects, per year.
March 15, 2017
Avoiding the health care run-around
The following originally appeared on The Upshot (copyright 2017, The New York Times Company).
You’ve all experienced it: There’s a problem with your health care bill, or you have difficulty getting coverage for the care you need. Your doctor or hospital tells you to talk to your insurer. Your insurer tells you to talk to your doctor or hospital. You’re stuck in an endless runaround.
A small patient advocacy industry has sprung up to help, but that help can cost several hundred dollars an hour. Is there a way to get the customer service we deserve?
Turns out, some kinds of health insurance plans provide better customer service than others. Among those that do are plans offered directly by hospitals or health systems, according to results from a recent study by me; Garret Johnson, now a medical student at Harvard; and Zoë Lyon, a research assistant at the Harvard T.H. Chan School of Public Health.
Our conclusions are based on analysis of Medicare Advantage plans — private insurance alternatives to traditional Medicare. Medicare Advantage plans are offered by major insurers like UnitedHealthcare, Humana, Aetna, BlueCross BlueShield affiliates and others. But nearly one-quarter of the plans are issued by hospitals or health systems. These provider-offered plans are more likely found in dense, urban areas in the Northeast and the West.
The government collects data on health care quality from surveys and medical claims, then aggregates them into ratings of plans. These are publicly reported in units of stars: Five stars represents the highest quality, and one the lowest. Our study, published this month in the health policy journal Health Affairs, found that provider-offered plans have higher quality ratings.
Plans offered by insurers have average ratings of just over 3.5 stars for both nondrug and drug service. An average provider-offered plan has quality ratings that are about one-third of a star higher for both, after adjusting for factors that could confound the comparison, like socioeconomic status and the types and number of doctors where plans are offered.
Our study dug deeper to examine the kinds of quality enhancements available in provider-offered plans. Some aspects of quality are clinically focused. For instance, measures of preventive screening — like that for colorectal cancer — or management of chronic conditions assess the quality of care delivered by doctors and hospitals in a plan’s networks. Provider-offered plans perform somewhat better than insurer-offered plans in such areas.
Other aspects of quality pertain to customer service. In measures of complaints, responsiveness to customers and the enrollees’ overall experiences, provider-offered plans really shine. In each area of customer service we examined, provider-offered plans are rated one-half star higher than insurer-offered ones. (This is a big difference. For comparison, over half of plans are within one star of each other in overall quality.)
These results make some sense. When a customer has an issue — like a problem with a hospital bill — the easiest thing for a health plan to do is pass it off to the hospital. Likewise, the hospital’s easiest course of action is to blame the health plan. The patient, stuck in the middle, is not likely to rate his plan (or hospital) highly for customer service in this case.
However, when the plan and hospital are one and the same, neither can pass the buck to the other. Problems may be resolved faster; they may be less likely to develop in the first place. This could lead to the higher customer satisfaction reflected in the quality ratings.
If the higher ratings are enough to interest you in trying a provider-offered plan, how would you find one? Unfortunately, there’s no readily accessible source to inform consumers (or researchers) about this feature of plans. Sometimes the plan’s name gives away the relationship. The UPMC Health Plan practically has the health system that offers it right in the name — UPMC stands for University of Pittsburgh Medical Center. In other cases, consumers can identify the relationship on plans’ or health systems’ websites. For example, the Vital Traditions plan website identifies as its parent company the largest nonprofit hospital system in Texas, Baylor Scott & White.
But in many cases, it’s not so easy to figure out. In fact, this is why there has been so little analysis of provider versus insurer plans. For our study, we had to scroll through hundreds of websites, news articles and documents to build a research data set on provider-offered plans from 2011 to 2015. Because of the work involved, there are very few studies on the subject. Another, published in Health Service Research by me, Roger Feldman of the University of Minnesota and Steven Pizer of Northeastern University, found a similar quality relationship when examining 2009 data.
That earlier study also found that provider-offered Medicare Advantage plans charge higher premiums. But a recent study of marketplace plans found that provider-offered ones are not necessarily the most expensive. For some, a higher premium may outweigh the benefits of greater quality, but for others it may not.
From our study, we can’t be certain that provider sponsorship of plans causes higher quality. It could be that higher-quality providers are the ones that choose to offer plans. Nevertheless, such tight integration between plans and providers is at least a signal of higher quality, even if it doesn’t cause it.
Recent trends suggest more health systems are offering plans in other health care markets for the working-age population, not just in Medicare Advantage. Not all markets may be hospitable to provider-offered plans, however. Some systems that did offer plans are pulling back. According to The Wall Street Journal, Catholic Health Initiatives, which runs over 100 hospitals across 18 states, is divesting itself of some of its health insurance plans. After struggles with profitability, Tenet Healthcare and several other health systems have said they will do the same.
Provider-offered plans may increase convenience for consumers. But the financial risk it confers on the organizations that offer them may be more than some can handle.
March 14, 2017
Healthcare Triage: One Republican Backup Plan for the AHCA: Cassidy-Collins
If the new AHCA doesn’t pass (which is definitely in the realm of possibility), Republicans in Congress will need to come up with another plan to fulfill their promise to repeal and replace Obamacare. Senators Susan Collins of Maine, and Bill Cassidy of Louisiana have a plan, we’re going to tell you about it. That’s the topic of this week’s Healthcare Triage.
We taped this before the AHCA was released. I don’t care. I think Cassidy-Collins may re-emerge and become more important if the AHCA falls apart.
Read the summary here.
The CBO report on the AHCA in as few words as I can manage
Just like last week, I’m trying to describe the report in a few words as I can manage, to make a Healthcare Triage script. The below is my attempt. I’m going to leave comments open, and I encourage you to tell me where I’m wrong or missed something. I don’t tape until tomorrow. You can also tweet me suggested changes. Text of the report here.
The Congressional Budget Office is charged with producing independent analyses of budgetary and economic issues to support the Congressional budget process. It’s a nonpartisan office, and its current director was appointed by the Republicans in Congress. Keith Hall is not generally considered a fan of the ACA, and you can go read some glowing quotes about him by then-Congressman and now-HHS Secretary Tom Price here.
Let’s be frank: the CBO report doesn’t look good for the AHCA. Let’s divide its findings into a number of domains in order to understand it more fully.
Insurance Coverage
In 2018, just next year, the AHCA would result in 14 million more people being uninsured than under current law. Most of that would come from repealing the mandate. Some would choose not to buy insurance cause they don’t have to (healthy people) and some because they couldn’t afford it.
By 2020, the number of additional uninsured due to the AHCA would be 21 million. By 2026, it would be 24 million. Most of the newly uninsured at that point would be due to changes in Medicaid (which I’ll get to in a bit).
The CBO agrees with me that the continuous coverage provisions might not work as planned. They think they will increase the number of people with insurance in 2018, but reduce the number in 2019 and beyond. In that first year, about a million people will buy insurance to enter the program, but each year after that, about 2 million will not because they will be forced to pay a penalty when they do. Those will be healthier people, by the way.
Fourteen million fewer getting insurance in the Medicaid program, 2 million fewer in the marketplaces, seven million fewer in employer-based coverage, and one million fewer from other sources. Under current law, it’s estimated that 28 million people might be uninsured in 2026. Under the AHCA, it would be 52 million people.
Medicaid
Medicaid takes it on the chin. The CBO thinks that over the next decade, spending on the program would be reduced by about $880 billion. As we discussed last week, the per capita block grants go up each year by medical CPI+1%. The CBO agrees with me that this is likely to rise more slowly than actual medical spending in Medicaid.
It estimates that CPI-M will go up 3.7% each year on agerage over the decade. Medicaid spending will go up 4.4% a year, though. That leaves a lot of money for the states to make up. Either they do that, or they start to cut.
Enrollment is expected to drop pretty impressively, by about 14 million in 2026. Before 2020, almost all those dropped from Medicaid are not expansion-eligible individuals, although the percentage from that population increases starting then through 2020.
Health Insurance Market Stability
If you listen to some politicians, they claim Obamacare is in a death spiral. Others, like me, think that’s massively overstating the case. But let’s listen to the CBO: “Under the AHCA, the subsidies available, added to the grants in the Patient and State Stability Fund, would stabilize the market.”
But the CBO also says the market is stable under current law. In essence, the AHCA doesn’t change much in that respect.
Premiums for Health Insurance
In 2018 and 2019, premiums would actually go up about 15-20% because with the elimination of the mandate, healthy people will leave the market and leave the risk pool sicker, and more expensive.
But, in 2020, the Patient and State Stability Fund could be used to offset the costs of the very sick. Insurers could also start to offer plans of lower actuarial value – which would allow for premiums to be lower. Of course, that means higher OOP payments, but I’ll get to that in a second. They also think healthier, younger people might return, lowering the price per beneficiary.
These changes will combine to let premiums be about 10% lower in 2026 than under current law.
Of course, there are averages. Older people are gonna get crushed and younger people will do better. More on that in a minute.
Details on Premiums and Subsidies on the Exchanges
Let’s take a closer look here. In 2026, under current law, if we look at someone who makes $26,500 a year, they all pay about $1700 in premiums for insurance regardless of income. That’s cause while insurance costs $5100 for a 21yo, $6500 for a 40yo, and $15,300 for a 64yo, the subsidies are big.
Under the AHCA, the cost of insurance itself is lower for the 21yo, slightly lower for the 40yo, but much higher for the 64yo. But the subsidies go way down, cause they don’t adjust for wealth. So the 21yo will pay $1450 (which is slightly less), but the 40yo pays $2400 (more), and the 64yo pays $14,600 (which is more than half their income). And this new insurance has an actuarial value about 20% lower, meaning that they have much higher OOP payments.
If they make $68,200, then under current law they get no subsidies, so their payments are the cost of insurance: $5100 for a 21yo, $6500 for a 40yo, and $15,300 for a 64yo. With the AHCA, though, they all do better, cause they get something in subsidies when they got nothing under the ACA. They pay the exact same as the poorer person: the 21yo pays $1450, the 40yo pays $2400, and the 64yo pays $14,600.
So the more well-off see some premium savings (but slightly higher OOP payments), but the poor get, well, hammered. Especially the older, poorer people.
Effects on the Federal Budget
There are massive reductions in spending under the AHCA. Outlays for Medicaid go down $880 billion. The elimination of the ACA’s subsidies in 2020 saves another $673 billion. Decreases in the employer-based health insurance market save another $70 billion. And repealing a tax credit to small employers for providing insurance saves $6 billion.
But! The new tax credits cost $361 billion. Getting rid of mandates and penalties costs another $210 billion. The Patient and State Stability Funds cost $80 billion. And reinstating DSH payments costs $43 billion.
And let’s not forget the tax cuts. About $600 billion in tax cuts, most to people at the very high end of the socioeconomic spectrum.
Bottom line: Spending goes down about $1.22 trillion dollars, and revenue goes down about $883 billion. Therefore, the CBO projects that the federal deficit would be reduced by $337 billion over a decade.
And since I get this question a lot, eliminating Planned Parenthood coverage saves (overall) $156 million over a decade. The technical reduced outlays are more, but that’s reduced by increases in Medicaid spending, thousands more births, and associated care. And because this is the real world and there are tradeoffs, lots of women will lose access to care in “areas without other health care clinics or medical practitioners who serve low-income populations.”
No, Secretary Price, you can’t fix the CBO score by regulating
With the release of the dismal CBO report on the American Health Care Act, the administration is playing defense. Secretary Price says the report is “just not believable” because it does not take into account the regulatory changes that he intends to make to bring down the cost of coverage. It also “ignored completely the other legislative activities that we’d be putting into place.”
This is all very vague, but what Price seems to have in mind is an alteration to the rule requiring insurers in the individual and small-group markets to cover the “essential health benefits.” If plans have to cover fewer things, the reasoning goes, they’ll be much cheaper, enabling millions of people to afford coverage that would otherwise be out of reach.
Don’t be fooled.
When it comes to essential health benefits, Congress has already been sidelined. Coverage requirements don’t directly affect the federal budget, which means they can’t be changed through reconciliation. And Democrats will filibuster any effort to water down the essential health benefits. So unless Mitch McConnell blows up the filibuster, there is no chance that Congress will act.
On the regulatory side, Price is hemmed in by the text of the ACA, which says that “the scope of the essential health benefits” must be “equal to the scope of benefits provided under a typical employer plan.” Price has some latitude to determine what counts as “typical,” but he can’t read the word out of the statute. He’s got to be able to identify a substantial number of plans in the employer market to use as a benchmark.
The Institute of Medicine looked into employer plans back when HHS was first considering what to do about the essential health benefits. It found that plans from one another in the scope of their coverage. Prominent insurers reported “that little of the variation in customizing coverage in either the large and small group market is due to differences in covered benefits as opposed to benefit design options.” Instead, insurers held down costs by networks and cost-sharing.
If most employer plans cover the same stuff, you can’t squeeze much juice out of a redefinition of the essential health benefits.
Yes, Price can make some changes at the margin. Under its current approach to essential health benefits, HHS allows the states to select an existing employer plan to use as a benchmark. As Helen Levy and I explained in an article we wrote a few years back, existing plans will necessarily cover all services mandated under state law. Not all of those services, however, need to be considered “essential” within the meaning of the ACA.
Take infertility treatment, which is an essential health benefit in (at least) those fifteen states with infertility mandates. In other states, however, some small group plans infertility treatment. Price could probably determine that plans that exclude such coverage are “typical” and redefine essential health benefits to categorically exclude infertility treatments. But that would yield only a decrease in premiums.
What Price can’t do is lop off whole benefit categories. The ACA is explicit, for example, that the essential health benefits must include treatments for maternity care and mental health disorders. Because Price can’t exclude big categories from coverage, he’ll struggle to redefine the essential health benefits in a manner that will drive down costs.
Plus, if Price were to define essential health benefits in an especially parsimonious manner, he’d face a lawsuit challenging his decision as unreasonable. (I for one would love to litigate that case.) The resulting legal uncertainty would drive premiums up, not down. And remember, too, that Price can only change the existing rule by going through notice-and-comment rulemaking, which will take at least a year, maybe more.
Price therefore can’t do much to drive down premiums by tinkering with the essential health benefits. What gives me pause, however, is the possibility that he might take a page from the Obama administration’s playbook and “delay” the implementation of the existing statutory requirements. Such a move would be unconstitutional and vulnerable to a legal challenge, but I don’t know if that will stop HHS: refusing to enforce the law might be the only way to give insurers room to materially narrow their scope of coverage.
Apart from this illegal possibility, however, don’t put much stock in Secretary Price’s vague claim that future regulatory changes will transform CBO’s coverage estimates. They can’t and they won’t.
March 13, 2017
Preserving wellness programs by infringing on privacy
A bill is moving through Congress—the Preserving Employee Wellness Programs Act—that would effectively allow businesses to require their employees to disclose lots of sensitive medical data, including their genetic information.
It’s an ugly piece of legislation. Explaining why is tricky, but bear with me.
* * *
The point of workplace wellness programs is to discriminate among employees. Those who adhere to the wellness program—whether by filling out a health assessment, taking a blood test, or attending smoking-cessation classes—pay less for their health coverage. Those who don’t, pay more.
At the same time, a bunch of federal laws aim to stop discrimination in the workplace. HIPAA is one such law: it prohibits employers from asking employees to pay more for their coverage based on their health status. Many wellness programs couldn’t exist in the face of that prohibition.
So, in HIPAA, Congress partly exempted wellness programs. They were allowed to discriminate a little bit based on health status. The ACA expanded HIPAA’s carve-out. Today, wellness programs can ask employees who don’t adhere to a wellness program to pay up to 30% more for their health coverage.
But Congress has never fully resolved the tension between federal antidiscrimination law and wellness programs. Take the Americans with Disabilities Act. It says that employers can’t ask their employees to take a medical exam, including a medical history, unless doing so is “voluntary.”
What if an employer imposes a 30% insurance surcharge on employees who refuse to do a health assessment? The surcharge would not be trivial. The cost of an average family plan in 2016 was $18,142; 30% of that is $5,443. With a penalty of that size, it’s nuts to say that a health assessment is still “voluntary.”
Nevertheless, the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission, which oversees wellness programs, has adopted a rule saying that ACA-compliant wellness programs are consistent with the ADA, voluntariness notwithstanding. A couple of courts have bought the argument. One of the courts reasoned that “even a strong incentive is still no more than an incentive; it is not compulsion.”
The mafia would happily endorse that sentiment, but it’s crazy to see it in a judicial decision. As I’ve explained before, the EEOC rule is unlawful and it’s vulnerable to legal challenge. An AARP lawsuit will soon work its way to the D.C. Circuit. The wellness industry is rightly worried that it could lose.
That’s where the new bill comes in. It says that wellness programs that comply with the ACA can never be involuntary. The AARP lawsuit would be deader than a doornail. Employers could effectively compel their employees to answer questions about their disabilities.
* * *
A similar dynamic is in play with the Genetic Information Nondiscrimination Act, which prohibits businesses from asking employees for their genetic information. The term “genetic information” is defined to exclude an employee’s medical history—that’s not closely enough connected to her genes. But genetic information includes information about any “manifestation of a disease or disorder in family members.”
The reason is simple: a family member’s illness may suggest a genetic propensity in the employee herself. And so, under GINA, asking an employee whether she has ever had breast cancer is OK. Asking whether her sister or mother has ever had breast cancer isn’t.
Under the new bill, however, it’s open season on your family’s medical history. You can refuse to answer, but good luck with that 30% surcharge.
If you think that’s no big deal, imagine that your spouse is an alcoholic or that your 22-year-old son was just diagnosed with schizophrenia. Employers aren’t supposed to use that kind of information to discriminate against you. But they’ll be sorely tempted: through your employer-sponsored coverage, they’re on the hook for your family’s medical expenses.
The bill goes further still. Under GINA, employers can’t insist on their employees’ genetic data. GINA, however, supplies an exception for data that are compiled as part of a wellness program and given to the employer in de-identified, aggregate form. The new legislation says that wellness programs “shall be considered to be in compliance” with that exception.
This is a little confusing. Would the bill bless all requests for genetic information, or only those requests that otherwise meet some of the terms of the exception? Read literally, I think it’s the former: any wellness program’s inquiry into an employee’s genetic history is deemed to be in “compliance” with the exception.
If that’s right, then the bill would allow your employer to insist on the disclosure of any genetic data. If you don’t want to answer, you don’t have to. Just cough up your $5,443 penalty.
* * *
Adrianna, Aaron, Austin, and I have a paper coming out soon detailing the dubious empirical and legal foundations of workplace wellness programs. For the very curious, here’s an excerpt examining some of the legal questions that I’ve just discussed.
But the bottom line on the new legislation is simple. The Preserving Employee Wellness Program Act sweeps aside federal antidiscrimination law in order to give businesses more power to root about in their employees’ lives. If wellness programs worked, maybe that’d be OK. But the evidence is overwhelming that most don’t work. This bill is just a naked, unearned giveaway to the wellness industry.
Oh, and on top of all of this, the bill would strip the EEOC of its authority to regulate wellness programs. Instead, that power would go to HHS, Labor, and Treasury. The effect would be to shift power from an independent agency that cares a lot about discrimination to agencies under the firm control of the Trump administration.
As I said, it’s an ugly bill.
Aaron E. Carroll's Blog
- Aaron E. Carroll's profile
- 42 followers
