More on this book
Community
Kindle Notes & Highlights
by
Adam Tooze
Read between
September 22, 2018 - February 28, 2019
The message that this communicated down the food chain was simple: We want more mortgage debt to process, and the worse the quality, the better. By the magic of independent probabilities, the worse the quality of the debt that entered into the tranching and pooling process, the more dramatic the effect. Substantial portions of undocumented, low-rated, high-yield debt emerged as AAA. In any boom, irresponsible, near criminal or outright fraudulent behavior is to be expected. But the mortgage securitization mechanism systematically produced this race to the bottom in mortgage lending quality. It
...more
Max liked this
At the hedge funds and private equity groups, individuals could earn hundreds of millions, or even billions, of dollars per annum. In 2007 the six top hedge fund managers earned at least a billion dollars each in compensation.
In August 2005 the theme of the conference was not the crisis brewing in the US housing market but a celebration in honor of the outgoing Fed chairman, Alan Greenspan. Most of the presentations were appropriately upbeat. But one rang an off note. It was given by Raghuram G. Rajan, an Indian by birth but a fully paid-up member of the American economics elite, professor at the Chicago Booth business school and chief economist at the IMF. His paper bore the heretical title “Has Financial Development Made the World Riskier?”57 Rajan worried that the dramatic expansion of modern financial
...more
Max liked this
The rise of China dominated contemporary perceptions of early twenty-first-century globalization. And the axis of imbalance that attracted most attention was that between China and the United States. Worries about geopolitics, Larry Summers’s balance of financial terror, Ben Bernanke’s savings glut, all pointed the finger in that direction. But if we map not annual flows but cross-border banking claims, this gives further proof of how one-sided the Sino-American view of the buildup to the crisis was. The central axis of world finance was not Asian-American but Euro-American. Indeed, of the six
...more
In the process, the European financial system came to function, in the words of Fed analysts, as a “global hedge fund,” borrowing short and lending long.16
If it is misleading to construct our image of financial globalization around the Sino-American trade balance, to imagine it as centered on US securitization with outsiders being “sucked in” misses the point too. In fact, the entire structure of international banking in the early twenty-first century was transatlantic. The new Wall Street was not geographically confined to the southern end of Manhattan. It was a North Atlantic system. The second node, detached from but integrally and inseparably connected to New York, was the City of London.17 In the nineteenth century, in the age of the gold
...more
Britain’s native banking industry under intense competitive pressure, Tony Blair’s New Labour government set about further streamlining the City’s regulatory system.24 Nine specialist regulators were combined into a single agency, the Financial Services Authority (FSA). It set a new low bar for financial oversight. Tony Blair’s chancellor, Gordon Brown, boasted that the FSA offered “not only light but limited regulation.”25 The FSA was mandated to achieve its “goals in the most efficient and effective way.” “[N]ot damaging the competitive position of the United Kingdom” was its top priority.26
...more
In the United States, under regulations that went back to 1934, such rehypothecation of collateral was strictly limited to no more than 140 percent of the collateral being held. In the UK there was no limit on rehypothecation. As a result, according to investigations by a team of analysts from the IMF, the City of London came to function as a “platform for higher leveraging not available in the United States.” The scale of this activity was enormous. According to the IMF team, trading in and out of London the main European and US banks achieved a collateral multiplication of 400 percent,
...more
For the resilience of a bank in the face of losses on its loan book, capital is the crucial criterion. The more capital a bank has, the more it is able to absorb losses. However, the larger a bank’s book of loans relative to its capital, the higher the rate of return it will be able to offer investors. That was the point of the elaborate legal structures designed to hold securitized assets off balance sheet, to minimize the capital invested and to maximize its leverage. Capital ratios were, therefore, one of the neuralgic points of bank governance.
Northern Rock had minimal exposure to US subprime. But that didn’t matter, because it sourced its funding from markets heavily used by banks that did. The bad news from Paribas on August 9 was enough to shut down the interbank lending markets and the market for asset-backed commercial paper. It was the seizure in the funding market that poleaxed the entire securitization business and in particular the European side, which had been most actively involved in the issuance of ABCP. Given Northern Rock’s extreme dependence on wholesale funding, it took only two working days after the markets dried
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
When news of a new round of mortgage failures hit the markets in March 2008 and hedge funds began emptying their prime brokerage accounts, quite suddenly the haircuts Bear Stearns faced in the bilateral repo market steepened and access to trilateral repo funding was shut off. A bank that in early March had easily been able to raise $100 billion overnight in exchange for good collateral could no longer fund itself. On Thursday, March 13, with its liquidity reserve down to only $2 billion, Bear’s directors were told that $14 billion in repos would not “roll” the next day and that they were at
...more
A conservative, free-market administration led by businessmen was proposing unlimited state spending to nationalize a large part of the housing finance system. The Republican electorate was outraged by the thought of assisting undeserving mortgage borrowers and the New Deal machinery that had aided and abetted their fecklessness. But to Paulson the systemic imperative was obvious. And President Bush stood behind him. “It was a tremendous act of political courage,” Paulson gushed, “It was as if, in the last days of his administration, the president were suddenly switching sides, supporting
...more
early in the morning of September 30 the Dublin government announced that for fear of dying it would commit suicide. As Europe turned on the morning news it learned that the Irish government was fully guaranteeing not just the deposits but all the liabilities of six major Irish banks for a period of two years. No other government had been advised in advance, nor had the ECB, nor had the Irish taxpayers.66 It stopped the run, but it left Ireland, with a population half the size of New York City, guaranteeing 440 billion euros in bank liabilities. The losses the banks incurred would bankrupt the
...more
Against the backdrop of the TARP debacle and the shambles in Europe, Gordon Brown’s scheme looked like a breakthrough. From New York, Paul Krugman lavished praise on Britain’s Labour government. Britain’s Social Democrats had figured out how to rescue financial capitalism.88 It certainly helped that the Labour government was less averse to nationalization than Hank Paulson was. Less charitably it might be said that since the 1990s, New Labour, like the Democrats in the United States, had entered into an enthusiastic partnership with the City of London. It was, therefore, no coincidence that it
...more
Every cent of this staggering flow of funds was repaid in full. Indeed, the Fed made profits of c. $4 billion on its swap lending in 2008–2009. But this sober accounting understates the drama of this innovation. Responding to the crisis in an improvised fashion, the Fed had reaffirmed the role of the dollar as the world’s reserve currency and established America’s central bank as the indispensable central node in the dollar network. Given the even vaster volume of daily transactions in global financial markets, it is not the sheer size of the effort that mattered. The Fed’s programs were
...more
At the top of the Fed’s list were Citigroup and Bank of America and the two highly stressed US investment banks, Merrill Lynch and Morgan Stanley, with their respective London operations. Then came a comprehensive list of the big European and American players in the global dollar banking business. Of the liquidity on one-month or three-month terms that the Fed provided to big banks, European banks took the majority. European banks and the London operations of the major US investment banks accounted for 23 percent even of the overnight primary dealer credit facility. When this support is added
...more
In Europe, the bullish CEOs of Deutsche Bank and Barclays claimed exceptional status because they avoided taking aid from their national governments. What the Fed data reveal is the hollowness of those boasts. The banks might have avoided state-sponsored recapitalization, but every major bank in the entire world was taking liquidity assistance on a grand scale from its local central bank, and either directly or indirectly by way of the swap lines from the Fed. Using the Fed’s records we can track the liquidity support provided to a bank like Barclays on a daily basis, revealing a first hump of
...more
What would happen if an oligarch failed in his responsibilities was demonstrated in June 2009 when Putin descended on Pikalevo, a small town south of St. Petersburg dominated by the metallurgical empire of Oleg Deripaska. Deripaska, who had once been listed as the richest man in Russia, with a fortune estimated at $28 billion, had seen it reduced to $3.5 billion. But that was no excuse for not paying wages.20 Indignant workers were blockading the Moscow highway, causing a 250-mile traffic jam. In front of the TV cameras Putin upbraided Deripaska. Tossing him a pen, the premier demanded that
...more
And if Russia was hard hit by the 2008 crisis, the impact on Eastern Europe was even worse. The shock to the most highly leveraged transition states of the former Communist bloc was staggering. If we compare the forecasts for 2010 made in October 2007 with the expected outturn two years later, we see how radically the crisis changed the outlook for the worst-hit countries in the region. The most extreme case was Latvia. One year into the crisis, in October 2009, the IMF’s forecast for Latvia’s GDP in 2010 was 39 percent lower than it had been in October 2007. Over the same two-year period,
...more
“Latvia may be a small country but it has vast repercussions.”52 One Central European minister of finance, who preferred to remain anonymous, predicted that the chain reaction across Central and Eastern Europe would take down at least half a dozen European banks. Latvia would play the role of a Lehman, or, even more ominously, that of the infamous Austrian Kreditanstalt in the financial crisis of 1931, the failure of which had precipitated Weimar Germany’s final slide toward disaster.
For the IMF, the standard prescription for a country in Latvia’s position was a one-off devaluation followed by debt restructuring or rescheduling. But the European Commission dug in its heels. Latvia was en route to eurozone membership. It must stay the course. If it needed to rebalance its current account it must do so through deflation and austerity. The results for Latvia were drastic. By the summer of 2009 house prices had plunged by 50 percent. Civil servants, including one-third of the country’s teachers, were fired and public salaries were slashed by 35 percent. Unemployment surged
...more
As a result, net exports accounted for a smaller share of Chinese GDP growth before 2008 than one might imagine. In fact, no more than one third of China’s growth from 1990 was driven by exports, with two thirds coming from domestic demand.7 This was a very different balance from that of a truly export-dependent economy, of which Germany was the quintessential example. With slow domestic investment and consumption, the vast majority of Germany’s growth after 2000 was accounted for by foreign demand. In China, far and away the main driver of growth was its enormous wave of domestic investment.
...more
Central Document No. 18 energized the networks that linked the Communist Party, local government and business interests. It was precisely this nexus that over the last generation had combined to supercharge China’s spectacular economic growth. But it was that same combination that also went a long way to explaining the lopsided character of China’s growth. To meet a central target or quota, there was always some regional highway connection, housing complex, bridge or industrial park to be built and profits to be made doing so. When the stimulus was launched it was precisely this chain reaction
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
Clearly the impetus for spending was massive. But from an economic point of view the vital question was how it was to be financed. This is the key question in any fiscal policy “stimulus.” If spending is paid for by tax increases, this negates any increase in purchasing power. Borrowing by issuing bonds will soak up private savings, which may divert the portfolios of private wealth holders away from other investments. Credit creation is the one surefire way to fund stimulus spending if the aim is immediately to revive an underemployed economy. Beijing’s stimulus was particularly effective
...more
If we add the government deficit at all levels to the growth in bank credit beyond the 15 percent per annum expansion that had been the norm in China over the previous years, we get a measure of the true scale of China’s stimulus. In 2009 its dimensions were extraordinary—950 billion yuan in deficit, 467 billion in additional bond finance and 5 trillion in bank loans beyond the previous growth norm, for a total stimulus of 6,487 billion RMB, or 19.3 percent of GDP.36
Despite the radical expectations projected onto him, Obama was by inclination a bipartisan centrist. What he had not reckoned with was the sheer violence of the conservative hostility toward him. There was no possibility of bipartisanship. Whereas at least a minority of Republicans had voted with the majority of the Democrats to pass the Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac bailouts and TARP, in January 2009 in the House of Representatives not a single Republican voted for the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, despite the tax cuts with which it was festooned.5 In the Senate only three did. It was
...more
Nevertheless, it was substantial. In absolute terms it was on a par with the spending of the New Deal. Though it was smaller in relation to a much larger national economy, the Obama stimulus was concentrated over a shorter space of time.10 In 2009 it placed America alongside the Asian states in the league of activists, outstripping any discretionary fiscal measures taken in Europe. And it worked. Despite the protestations of “freshwater” free-market economists and the complex economic arguments directed against “naïve” Keynesian “pump priming,” every reputable econometric study found that the
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
Part of the answer is that the transition team did not fully grasp the scale of the tsunami that was descending on the US economy. From preparatory documents circulated within the transition team in early January 2009, we know that the worst-case scenario envisioned by Obama’s staff was for unemployment to reach 9 percent with no stimulus.14 In fact, even with the largest government-spending program in American history, unemployment topped 10.5 percent. But despite this underestimate, it is clear that the top macroeconomists in the Obama transition team did, in fact, realize that the stimulus
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
The great political might-have-been of the early Obama administration is why, alongside TARP and the fiscal stimulus, the White House did not start by pushing a comprehensive relief program for home owners.15 While the banks and lenders were bailed out, 9.3 million American families lost their homes to foreclosure, surrendered their home to a lender or were forced to resort to a distress sale.16 The m...
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
The discretionary spending component of the Obama stimulus did not begin in earnest until June 2009, at which point the labor market was close to bottoming out.20 The less commonly noted corollary is that the open-handed fiscal stance of the first year of the Obama administration was in large part an inheritance of decisions and nondecisions made in 2008, while the future president was still in the Senate.
As profits, wages and spending all declined, this automatically generated a deficit and thus an offsetting public stimulus. This puts a rather different perspective on the fiscal policy battles at the G20. Though Germany, France and Italy steered clear of the kind of stimulus package launched by the Obama administration, let alone that trumpeted by Beijing, their deficits were widening too. As the private sector deleveraged and cut its spending, they too saw huge nondiscretionary deficits. Indeed, it would have taken a heroic and truly perverse act of austerity to prevent these automatic
...more
For macroeconomists this was a cause to celebrate the stabilizing properties of the modern tax and welfare state. For fiscal hawks it was a cause of deep concern. In the long run those debts would require higher taxes to service and repay them. This would pose major political challenges. And how would capital markets react? According to the script set out by conventional fiscal conservatism, one might have expected serious and immediate repercussions. Would the debt shock trigger the loss of confidence that Orszag and Rubin and so many others had warned about? How would savers be induced to
...more
In the event, Summers and the other skeptics were proven right. There was no run against Treasurys. The bond vigilantes were a spook. America’s households were rebuilding their savings. Mutual funds were shifting out of risky mortgage bonds. Everyone wanted Treasurys. These were the kinds of systemic macroeconomic and financial mechanics that all too often escape fiscal hawks, who view the public budget like that of a private household. When the private sector is undergoing a shock episode of deleveraging, when the savings rate is surging as it was in 2009, what is needed to preserve the
...more
As in the UK and the United States, this helped to stabilize the government debt market, but there was a crucial difference. In the United States and the UK the central banks were pushing liquidity into the banking system. By contrast, in the eurozone, it was the balance sheets of the banks that absorbed the sovereign debt.
It was not markets but the cross-party consensus on fiscal consolidation that had emerged before the crisis that dictated a decisive and irrevocable turn toward austerity. It was a decision driven by a long-term vision of competitiveness and retrenchment, the lobbying of taxpayer and business advocates and the regional interests of the rich states of western Germany.33 It was a choice that would change the politics not just of Germany but of the eurozone as a whole.
Though the Obama stimulus crested in the second year of his presidency, this was offset in 2010 by cuts to other areas of federal spending and a crushing contraction in state and local spending. Though it suited no one to acknowledge the fact, between 2009 and 2010 Germany’s deficit was actually increasing more rapidly than that of the United States.44 Though the arguments were apparently more transparent, the politics of fiscal policy in the wake of the crisis were in their own way no less opaque than those that framed monetary policy.
In Britain, the most egregious case was RBS, a now majority state-owned bank that announced in February 2009 that it intended to honor £1 billion in bonus contracts.4 In the United States the figures were far larger. In the 2008 bonus season, after suffering tens of billions in losses, Wall Street paid out $18.4 billion to its top staff. That was two and a half times the amount that Congress approved for the president’s priority of modernizing America’s broadband infrastructure. Alternatively, if it had been retained by the banks, it would have made a substantial contribution toward their
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
The result was a sprawling piece of legislation running to 849 pages.34 Rather than offering a single coherent thesis, the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, commonly known as Dodd-Frank, embodied a compendium of crisis diagnoses. Was the crisis due to mass predation of poorly informed borrowers? In which case what was needed was Elizabeth Warren’s Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection (Title X). Was it opaque over-the-counter derivatives that had blown up the system? In which case the fix was transparent, market-based trading of derivatives (Title VII—Wall Street Transparency
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
For Geithner the “populist fury” of the “atonement agenda” was a dangerous distraction from the tough-minded technical business of addressing a crisis.44 But the grief and distress caused by the crisis were forces to be reckoned with. They ran through American society in waves, and early 2010, as Dodd-Frank reached a critical point in its labored passage through Congress, was one such moment. Three years since the real estate bubble burst, the full effects of the credit crunch and mass unemployment were making themselves felt. Between 2007 and 2009, 2.5 million homes had been foreclosed and
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
The contrast in fortunes between Wall Street and Main Street was increasingly intolerable. The big banks had been bailed out. Some of the most unscrupulous bosses might face legal action, but they were not facing personal ruin. They retired to lifestyles of wealth and comfort.46 None had gone to jail. And those at the top of the tree on Wall Street were bouncing back apparently without shame or second thought. The bonus season in 2009 was better than ever, netting $145 billion for the executives at the top investment banks, asset managers and hedge funds, as compared with $117 billion in
...more
TARP, followed by the stress tests, the Dodd-Frank regime and capital planning, put the American banking system on a forced road to recovery. It foreclosed more radical options. The banks remained too big to fail. Far from downsizing or breaking them up, by 2013, J.P. Morgan, Goldman Sachs, Bank of America, Citigroup, Wells Fargo and Morgan Stanley were 37 percent larger than they were in 2008.73 The resources of the state were put one-sidedly at the service of management and shareholders. But if the aim was to get America’s banks out of the emergency ward, it worked. As Geithner insisted, the
...more
By contrast, the lack of comprehensive recapitalization of Europe’s wounded banking system was an omission that marks one of the fundamental turning points in the crisis. With the help of low-interest loans from Trichet’s ECB, many banks resorted to the makeshift of pumping up their profits by buying higher-yielding government debt. But the failure to build new capital would leave the European banks in no position to absorb any further shocks. While the United States began to stabilize, in Europe the banking crisis of 2008 would merge a year later with a new crisis: a panic in the eurozone
...more
This was the basic dilemma of the eurozone debt crisis. Greece needed a write-off. The Germans were not opposed and favored haircutting the creditors. But Greece’s PASOK government did not want to pay the price for a problem in large part created by its predecessor. It wasn’t just the state’s debts that would have to be restructured but the Greek banking system too. The entire Greek social and political fabric was at stake. The French opposed a write-off and Paris had backing not just from other European debtor nations but from the ECB as well. The ECB was aghast at the prospect of a sovereign
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
If the ECB was a central bank, like the Fed or the Bank of England, there was no need for there to be a sovereign debt crisis at all. Greece had not borrowed in dollars. It had borrowed in euros and had delegated the sovereign power to print its own currency to the ECB. Its fate and that of the entire rest of the eurozone was in Trichet’s hands. All the ECB had to do to stop the destabilizing surge in Greek interest rates was to do what central banks do all over the world: buy sovereign bonds. Of course, bond buying was no long-term solution. Greece needed restructuring, fiscal discipline and
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
But the White House made one thing clear. There could be no talk of debt restructuring. “We cannot have another Lehman,” Obama emphasized. Whether Greece’s debts were sustainable was not America’s concern. Washington’s priority was containing financial contagion. Restructuring could not be contemplated until the Europeans had found a way to stabilize bond markets and were ready to push through wholesale recapitalization of Europe’s banks. And given the Franco-German deadlock, no such agreement seemed likely.
It was from this force field of interests that the first iteration of extend-and-pretend emerged. Europe entered an emergency regime defined not by a single sovereign author, but by the absence of any such authority.35
A committee of the EU, the ECB and the IMF would make up the soon to be infamous “troika,” dictating policy to Greece and the other “program countries.” What was ruled out was restructuring. On that Washington sided with the French and the ECB. Existing Greek debt would be paid off with new loans from the troika, whether or not the result was sustainable. The IMF would have to bend its operating procedures to the occasion. To satisfy Merkel’s insistence on the Lisbon rules, the “European” component would not consist of measures taken collectively via the central institutions in Brussels or
...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
Karolos Papoulias, the grizzled president of the Hellenic Republic and veteran of the Greek resistance in World War II, declared: “Our country has reached the edge of the abyss.”50 On May 6, the Greek parliament convened to vote through what was the most draconian austerity program ever proposed to a modern democracy. That morning, the ECB board was meeting in Lisbon and reporters e-mailed the news that the imperious Jean-Claude Trichet had refused even to discuss the possibility of stepping in to buy Greek bonds.