Crashed: How a Decade of Financial Crises Changed the World
Rate it:
Open Preview
11%
Flag icon
Whereas the US crisis involved overextended banks and mortgage borrowers impelled by greed and financial excess, the eurozone crisis would revolve around quintessentially European themes of public finance and national sovereignty.
12%
Flag icon
The decisive force in European politics for the next decade and beyond would be German Christian Democracy and its leader, Angela Merkel.
12%
Flag icon
Merkel has come to be seen as the figurehead of Europe’s political center—oscillating between conservative stances on economic and financial policy and cultural modernization.16 When she first emerged on the political scene her profile was harder edged. In the 2005 election that brought her to power, Merkel ran on a strong promarket platform. It was unpopular and she subsequently softened her stance. But there is little doubt that the 2005 agenda expressed the chancellor’s basic personal vision. It can be summarized in three numbers: 7, 25 and 50. As Merkel is fond of pointing out, Europe has ...more
12%
Flag icon
that means first of all clearing up our financial situation, our budgets. We have a demographic problem. We know that we have too few young people and nevertheless we live at the expense of the future by running up debts. That means that we rob future generations of their room for investment and development and that is immoral.”18 Needless to say, this was music to the ears of business lobbyists concerned to see taxation and state spending held in check. But Angela Merkel’s first government was a grand coalition with the defeated SPD.19 Fiscal consolidation, like Hartz IV, commanded a ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
12%
Flag icon
2006, as Merkel’s grand coalition took office, the mood in the western Länder, and particularly the rich southern states, was resentful. They had been conscripted into a gigantic act of solidarity with the East. Now they had had enough. Capping deficits was a not-so-covert promise to the rich southern states to rebalance priorities away from the needy and indebted eastern and northern members of the Bund. Fatefully for the future of the eurozone, the problem of fiscal control was cast by German politics already from the early 2000s as one of equity within a federal transfer union. Well before ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
12%
Flag icon
The rise of China and the funding problems of the modern welfare state were common challenges. The Bush administration might have been political poison in Europe. But in the late 1990s, Clinton’s Democrats had been an inspiration
12%
Flag icon
for Gerhard Schroeder’s Red-Green coalition.24 Merkel was nothing if not an Atlanticist. But if there was a common agenda, there were common blind spots too. For all the focus in the eurozone on the need to make labor responsive to the demands of global competition, for all the calls for common fiscal discipline, there was an almost total lack of recognition of the destabilizing forces unleashed by global finance. In Europe, as in the United States, it was politicians, workers and welfare recipients who were seen as the problem, not banks or financial markets.
12%
Flag icon
If Europe did not have a common fiscal policy or labor market policy, it did at least have a common monetary policy. Its guardian was the ECB,
12%
Flag icon
To prevent it from being put to work as a vehicle of fiscal policy, it was banned from monetizing newly issued government debt.
12%
Flag icon
Unlike the Fed, which had a dual mandate for price stability and maximum employment, the ECB had price stability as its only target. All this made the ECB the most remote of all the modern central banks.26 To call it apolitical would be a misnomer, because it, in fact, entrenched a conservative bias against inflation as the unquestionable doxa of Europe. Nor would it be fair to say that anti-inflation politics were the ECB’s only ambition. It also wanted to promote Europe as a financial center and the euro as a reserve currency, and that meant actively developing European debt markets. ...more
12%
Flag icon
Faced with the financial pressures exercised by Germany, France had actively promoted the market for its own debt by offering American-style repo facilities.27 The easier it was to trade French debt for instant liquidity, the more actively it would be purchased and the more accepting the market would be of France’s borrowing requirements. Over the resistance of the Bundesbank, repo was adopted as a core operational model by the ECB. Unlike the more traditional central banks, like the Bank of England or the Fed, the ECB did not hold large quantities of government debt. It managed Europe’s ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
12%
Flag icon
If it had wished to maximize pressure on Europe’s government to preserve fiscal discipline, the ECB could have adopted a discriminatory system of nationally specific repo haircuts, imposing tougher conditions on less credible peripheral eurozone borrowers. Haircuts in the bilateral repo market in the United States varied widely across different types of bonds. A higher haircut would require banks to hold more capital against their bond holdings and shrink their portfolios of that debt. In Europe in the late 1990s, Greece had had to offer far higher interest rates to attract lenders than had ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
12%
Flag icon
government bonds. The result was a self-reflexive loop in which the ECB relied on markets to exercise discipline over public borrowers while the markets came to assume that the ECB’s “one bond” policy implied an implicit European guarantee for even the weakest borrowers. The result was that Greece and Portugal could borrow on terms that were better than ever before in...
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
13%
Flag icon
The backdrop to the eurozone crisis was, indeed, a gigantic surge in debt, but it was in the private, not the public, sector. The eurozone played host to the same runaway, market-driven process of credit creation that European banks were contributing to so actively in the North Atlantic economy.
13%
Flag icon
As the Financial Times’s economic commentator Martin Sandbu has remarked, it was the euro’s “great misfortune” to be born “into the greatest private credit bubble of all time.”
13%
Flag icon
In 2007 more than $500 billion in loans were securitized in Europe. In 2008 the total reached $750 billion in European asset-backed security issuance with UK and Spanish banks particularly active.
13%
Flag icon
Once again, as in the case of America’s international finances, it is easy to deceive oneself about the direction of these intra-European flows. We have a clear map of the economic hierarchy of Europe in our heads. We know where the loans went—Greece, Spain, Ireland. We know that Germany was the main “surplus” and “creditor” nation. So does that mean that Germany financed the credit boom? Certainly it had the largest trade surplus and was thus the largest net exporter of capital. But as far as overall financial flows within Europe are concerned, that simple mental map is as misleading as the ...more
13%
Flag icon
But if we focus on intra-European flows, it is clear that Germany, despite its export prowess, did not dominate the European financial system. Germany was the largest net lender. Its status was like that of China in relation to the US economy. But financial flows within Europe no more mapped onto trade than they did in the world economy. Germany was a champion exporter of cars and machinery, but in banking
13%
Flag icon
and finance others led the field. The UK, France, the Benelux and Ireland (the latter hidden within the category “Rest of Euro area”) were the key hubs for financial flows. The City of London, home to banks from around the world, including all the leading German banks, stands out as the major financial partner for every eurozone member, even though it was not a member of the currency union. France and the Benelux were particularly important because they served as channels through which funds flowed into the eurozone from the outside. American and other lenders from the rest of the world ...more
13%
Flag icon
The flow of funds around Europe, as around the global economy, was driven not by trade flows but by the business logic of bankers, who sought out the cheapest funding and the best returns. The upward spiral of asset prices and balance sheets that drove the US boom was even more pronounced in Europe. Between 2001 and 2006, Greece, Finland, Sweden,
13%
Flag icon
Belgium, Denmark, the UK, France, Ireland and Spain all experienced real estate booms more severe than those that energized the United States. In Ireland and Spain, the combination of credit growth and house price inflation was truly explosive.
13%
Flag icon
It was these credit-fueled booms that drove the trade and fiscal imbalances of the eurozone, rather than the other way around. The huge influx of credit from all over the world to a hot spot like Spain inflated economic activity there. This generated healthy tax revenues for Madrid, which proudly boasted a fiscal surplus. It also generated export orders for Germany. Foreign demand gave a boost to the languishing German economy, raising incomes and profits.38 But German households and businesses did not want to spend their income increment in Germany, on either consumption or investment. The ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
13%
Flag icon
It would later be said that the ECB should have done more to dampen the boom in Ireland and Spain. And it is clearly true that this was made more difficult by the fact that it set one interest rate for the entire eurozone. In effect, by setting low rates, the ECB prioritized the need to stimulate the German economy over restraining the boom in the periphery. It was a reasonable decision. Germany’s economy is far bigger. Furthermore, given the rates of return that beckoned in the hot spots of the European economy, it is wishful thinking to imagine that the ECB could have curbed the boom with a ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
13%
Flag icon
Banco Santander were emerging as global players. Fashion giant Zara made its owner Amancio Ortega the richest billionaire in Europe. Prime Minister José Luis Rodríguez Zapatero was lobbying for Spain to be invited to join the top table in an expanded G8. With lean social services and booming tax revenues, Spain’s public budget was in far better shape than that of France or Germany. Why put the brakes on such a healthy-looking burst of private sector growth?
13%
Flag icon
Among Ireland’s tiny political elite a similar spirit of ebullience prevailed. Coddled by EU investment and incestuously connected with bankers and developers, politicians boasted of the global attractions of Dublin’s International Financial Services Center. Ireland’s tax system enabled foreign corporations to spirit hundreds of billions of dollars in profit past tax authorities in the United States and the rest of Europe.
13%
Flag icon
But Europe’s chief problem was not the lack of a fiscal fire code. Its problem was the lack of a financial fire department.46 The failure of state building that mattered most was not fiscal union but the failure to build the capacity to handle a banking crisis. Coping with highly integrated financial capitalism requires a state that is disciplined, has the capacity to act and has the will to do so. Coping with a banking crisis on the scale that was brewing in Europe required a very capable state indeed.
13%
Flag icon
How badly such a facility was needed becomes clear only when we put together the local and global activities of Europe’s banks, to get a full view of their spectacularly overinflated growth. America’s banks were very big and very important to global finance. But it was in Europe that bank finance had grown most disproportionately.47 Europe’s banks had always been large. Unlike the United States, where equity and bond markets were the main sources of business finance, Europe’s economies had long relied heavily on bank lending. But spreading out across the EU and feeding off the transatlantic ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
13%
Flag icon
It was a monetary union that unified financial markets but provided none of the institutions of governance required for a banking union. If there was one urgent reason why Europe truly did need a fiscal constitution it was to provide the financial underpinning for a giant deposit insurance and bailout fund. In the late 1990s, as European Monetary Union approached, Larry Summers had the temerity to ask an international gathering of financial experts: “Could the Europeans here explain to me what happens if a bank in Spain gets into serious trouble? What are the respective responsibilities of
14%
Flag icon
the Spanish supervision authorities, the Spanish central bank, the ECB, and Brussels?”
14%
Flag icon
No one in the United States wanted to think about bank failures either, not in 1997 and not in 2007.
14%
Flag icon
The difference was that when the unthinkable happened, the United States had a structure of federal government within which to improvise a response. The misfortune of the EU was that when the crisis struck, it not only lacked such structures. The crisis came at a moment when the EU’s efforts to build a more robust constitutional framework had run up against basic political limits.
14%
Flag icon
Up to the early 2000s, the EU operated against a backdrop of what political scientists called a “permissive consensus.”51 Europe’s population accepted the gradual push for ever closer union without enthusiasm but also without protest. The EU is not an obtrusive presence. Contrary to prevailing myth, the EU is by no means a gigantic bureaucracy. The EU employs fewer people than most medium-sized cities. But it was a sprawling, incoherent constitutional structure lacking in democratic accountability. It was clearly unsatisfactory and would become even more so once the EU expanded in 2004 to ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
14%
Flag icon
But on May 29, 2005, the constitution was rejected by popular referenda in France and then, in June, in the Netherlands. Left-wing hostility to the promarket character of the EU and nationalist hostility to Brussels united to deliver solid majorities against it. It was a profound shock. The permissive consensus was dead. Whatever the rights and wrongs of the constitution, popular democracy had asserted itself and Europe’s elite were left in disarray.54 Given the reality of increasingly close economic and financial integration and the extension of the EU to Eastern Europe, the project of ...more
14%
Flag icon
the Lisbon Treaty of December 2007. Like the constitution it replaced, the Lisbon Treaty merged the multiple pillars of the European integration project into a single European Union with a population of 500 million. It created a new foreign and security policy for the EU. It streamlined the commission and established the principle of majority voting that was essential to make the vastly expanded structure manageable. But above all, it institutionalized the council as the representation of Europe’s national governments and created a presidency of the council as its standing representative. It ...more
14%
Flag icon
The Lisbon Treaty enshrined intergovernmentalism and Europe’s voters had shown their willingness to exercise a veto over steps beyond that. How, given this disequilibrium, the EU would respond to an unforeseen crisis was anyone’s guess. And that observation went beyond finance.
14%
Flag icon
If one compares American and European policy discussion in the early 2000s, one sees that they shared many preoccupations. Policy experts on both continents were focused on fiscal discipline and international competitiveness, supply side incentives, efficient government spending, deficits, evidence-based welfare policy, education reform and flexible labor markets. These were the shibboleths of the watered-down, supply-side market economics inherited from the days of Reagan and Thatcher and the Washington Consensus of the 1990s. The policy communities on both sides of the Atlantic also shared ...more
14%
Flag icon
If we are looking for one crucial difference it is surely this: From the morning of September 11, 2001, America was a superpower at war. Not only that, under the Bush administration, it was a regime pursuing a global war on terror. The initial European reaction to the attacks of 9/11 was one of solidarity. The ouster of the Taliban from Kabul enjoyed general support. But over the winter of 2002–2003, as Washington and London pushed toward the invasion of Iraq, that sense of common commitment evaporated. The German and French governments came out in opposition to war, as did millions of ...more
14%
Flag icon
A wide gulf conventionally separates accounts of global geopolitics in the wake of 9/11 from our narratives of the genesis of the financial crisis. But if we listen closely it is clear that the quagmire of Iraq haunted the Washington policy-making elite in the early 2000s, awakening nightmarish memories of Vietnam and the crisis of American power and authority of the 1930s. The rise of China added to the sense of menace. Larry Summers’s description of the Sino-American trade balance as a balance of financial terror was telling. That was not how the Germans or the Dutch thought about their ...more
14%
Flag icon
In terms of political culture the differences are undeniable. But to take the loudly proclaimed transatlantic alienation of the early 2000s at face value as a description of economic or geopolitical reality would be self-deceiving in a double sense.60 The idea that “social Europe” had deviated in any essential way from the logic of turbocharged “financial capitalism” as exemplified by America was an illusion. In fact, Europe’s financial capitalism was even more spectacularly overgrown and it owed a large part of its growth to its deep entanglement in the American boom. Furthermore, whatever ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
14%
Flag icon
to deny the fact, in the post–cold war world, it was far from geopolitically inert. It entertained complex relations with its neighbors in the Mediterranean and in Eastern Europe that could not easily be disentangled from the hard power of the NATO alliance or coercive border policing. And this would matter, because whereas the EU kept its distance from the Middle East imbroglio and refused to see the rise of China as a geopolitical threat, it would be on Europe’s doorstep that a violent great power confrontation would erupt, and it did so just as the world banking ...
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
14%
Flag icon
Russia’s return to the world stage in the early 2000s owed even more to global economic growth than did the rise of China. Russia poured oil and gas into world markets. Its banks and industrial corporations borrowed enthusiastically in Europe and the United States. Like China it held a huge reserve of dollars, but unlike China its financial and economic interrelationship with the United States was indirect. Russia did not earn its dollars by exporting to the United States. It sold its gas and oil to Europe and Asia. Furthermore, whereas the Chinese Communist Party approached the West with ...more
14%
Flag icon
In Europe, unlike in Asia, the triumph of “the West” over communism was absolute. It was a triumph of both hard and soft power, military, political and economic might.
14%
Flag icon
This was the backdrop against which NATO and the EU decided on enlargement to the East, stabilizing the immediate crisis, offering a future direction and permanently redrawing the geopolitical map.7 The double expansion of EU and NATO was not a coordinated affair. It was driven as much by the East Europeans themselves as by Washington, Berlin and Paris. Poland, Hungary, the Czechs and the Slovaks—the Visegrád group—began pushing for NATO membership as early as February 1991. The EU followed up with an association agreement. But the EU’s decision for enlargement did not follow until 1993, with ...more
15%
Flag icon
It took fifteen years from the end of the cold war. There were second thoughts in Washington, and many West European governments were reluctant to embark on the eastward expansion. The costs were likely to be huge. The risk of provoking Russia was obvious. In 2003 the divisions over the invasion of Iraq were deep and embarrassing.8 The East Europeans who were candidates for both NATO and EU membership had to choose. On one side stood Berlin and Paris in opposition to the war. On the other side were Washington, London and their supporters in Madrid and Rome. Eastern Europe opted overwhelmingly ...more
15%
Flag icon
Prodi talked as though the EU would soon emerge as a fully featured state, combining both soft and hard power. But, in fact, the geopolitical configuration of the post–cold war world was more uncertain and ramshackle than that. The EU never developed its own hard-power capabilities. Not only was European military cooperation factious and frowned upon by Washington, but the European states all took the peace dividend. In light of Russia’s weakness, what reason was there not to run down their substantial cold war military establishments? It was this decision that laid the basis for the ...more
16%
Flag icon
It invited the Russians to ensure that Georgia and Ukraine were never in a fit state to take the next step toward NATO accession. It invited Georgia, Ukraine and their sponsors to force the pace. Ambiguity was a formula for escalation. And both sides responded accordingly.
16%
Flag icon
sell Fannie and Freddie securities on the market.’”53 The fragility of America’s mortgage market was about to be turned into a geopolitical weapon.
16%
Flag icon
But over the course of 2008, Russia did unload its portfolio of $100 billion of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac bonds.
16%
Flag icon
early August 2008, with Russian encouragement, irregular forces in the rebel province of South Ossetia began shelling positions of the Georgian army.56 On August 7, apparently believing that they had Washington’s approval, the Georgian government took the bait. A sudden counterstrike by Georgia’s American-trained army would subdue Ossetia and Abkhazia, settle the outstanding territorial questions and clear the way for a successful NATO membership application. As the awe-inspiring opening ceremony of the Beijing Olympics exploded across Western TV screens, Georgia launched its army and air ...more
16%
Flag icon
undersized forces, inflicting hundreds of casualties. According to Georgian sources, 230,000 civilians were put to flight. After a rapid advance, Russian tanks halted on the Gori-Tbilisi highway, an hour’s drive from the capital.
1 5 10