The Anglosphere's long shadow

My Times column of 30 December 2013:



It was only five years ago that “Anglo-Saxon”
economics was discredited and finished. Continental or Chinese
capitalism, dirigiste and heavily regulated, was the future. Yet
here’s the Centre for Economics and Business Research last week
saying that Britain is on course to remain the sixth or seventh
biggest economy until 2028, by when it is poised to pass Germany,
mainly for demographic reasons. Three others of the top ten will be
its former colonies: the US, India and Canada.



Even today, of the IMF’s top ten countries by per capita income,
four are part of the Anglo-Saxon diaspora — the United States,
Canada, Australia and Singapore, (Hong Kong would be there too if
it were a country). Apart from Switzerland, all of the others are
small city- or petro-states: San Marino, Brunei, Qatar, Luxembourg,
Norway. It appears that we ain’t dead yet.



League tables mean little, of course, and predictions even less.
Nonetheless, there is something resilient about the “Anglosphere”
model of running a country. The recent book by Daniel Hannan MEP
— How we Invented Freedom and Why it
Matters
— might have been titled to annoy foreigners, but
it contains a challenging idea. Bottom-up systems work best.



As Hannan points out, while we tend to stress the differences
between Britain and America, foreigners usually see the
similarities. The secret ingredient of the Anglosphere is not, of
course, racial. We can bury the Victorian notion that there is
something specially clever or tough about pale-skinned folk with
mostly Celtic DNA, mostly Saxon words and a mostly Protestant
faith.



Nor was it inevitable in the Whig-history sense. It was not
manifest destiny, but a chain of semi-happy accidents that gave the
English-speaking people their chance — including a sea channel to
protect against invaders, a randy king, a Dutch commercial
takeover, a coastal coalfield, a brilliant customs official from
Kirkcaldy, and a well timed tax revolt.



The secret is institutional. For Hannan, the habit of liberty
under the law proved good at generating prosperity wherever it was
adopted and whatever the skin colour of the people who caught it —
and even if it was sometimes honoured in the breach. It was a
peculiarity of the British that, early on, they got into the habit
of dispersing both property and power and never quite lost that
habit even under some strong Norman or Tudor rulers.



The monarchy was at least partly elective, the common law was
evolutionary and derived from cases rather than principles,
property was at least partly sacred, the press was fairly free,
Parliament was eventually sovereign. The Government was subject to
the law, rather than the other way round. Even in the Middle Ages
these features were visible to an unusual degree in Britain.



The common law plays a central role in Hannan’s argument — what
he calls “that beautiful, anomalous system that belongs to the
people, not the state”. Having government under the law, rather
than in charge of it, gave rise to security of property and
contract, which proved peculiarly helpful when the free market came
along and tipped the balance of incentive from predation to
production. The roots of these institutions go very deep into Saxon
times but many of the key features came together in 1688 and
1787.



For all its periodic lurches into hierarchy and imperialism, the
Anglosphere has always hemmed in its rulers with bottom-up
traditions. That is what the English Civil War and the American War
of Independence shared — two episodes in the same family argument
with surprising philosophical and religious similarities. Hannan
makes clear how much the Roundheads and the rebels both harked back
to Magna Carta and what they saw as their birthright of
liberty.



The British version of the Protestant Reformation adopted the
rejection of top-down authority, but not its usual Calvinist
substitute: providential predestination. So Protestantism became
enmeshed with freedom in that potent recipe known as Whiggery.
Besides, scholars now think the British Reformation owes as much or
more to old Lollard ideas as to new Lutheran ones. Even the English
language, unusually, never had a top-down academy to decide how it
could evolve.



The combination of free trade and some recourse against
arbitrary law did happen elsewhere, too. Phoenicia, ancient Athens,
Ashokan India, Song China, Abbasid Arabia, Renaissance Italy,
17th-century Holland — they all tried it, at least in part, with
astonishing results for their prosperity. But the experiments all
petered out because of some combination of invasion, superstition
or bureaucracy. For most of the time in most of the world, what
Hannan calls the Ming-Mogul-Ottoman habit of expecting laws to come
down from above — of uniformity, centralisation, high taxation and
state control — prevailed.



So the obvious question is whether the Anglo-Saxon experiment
with liberty under the law can last till 2028 as the CEBR report
implicitly assumes. Hannan is far from optimistic. He sees the EU
steadily undermining the common law, imposing rules and taxes
passed by appointed rather than elected commissioners, erecting
trade barriers with the rest of the world, and assuming that there
is little middle ground between regulated and compulsory.



Creeping centralisation afflicts other parts of the Anglosphere
but Hannan notes that America, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and
India are busy negotiating progressively deeper free-trade
agreements among themselves. Britain, as an EU member, cannot sign
independent commercial agreements. Imagine if it could — if we
regained the power to represent ourselves at international
negotiations and aim for more access to vast, Asian markets rather
than cramped and dwindling European ones. Imagine being able to
take our own decisions about innovation — genetically modified
crops, for example. That alone would not secure our position in the
2030 league table, but it would certainly help.

 •  0 comments  •  flag
Share on Twitter
Published on January 02, 2014 14:43
No comments have been added yet.


Matt Ridley's Blog

Matt Ridley
Matt Ridley isn't a Goodreads Author (yet), but they do have a blog, so here are some recent posts imported from their feed.
Follow Matt Ridley's blog with rss.