Lords of Finance: The Bankers Who Broke the World
Rate it:
Open Preview
Read between August 15 - August 20, 2022
27%
Flag icon
The committee should jettison the whole concept of “capacity to pay,” he argued. It was impossible to know what this number was. Too many imponderables entered into the calculation, involving such questions as: How much could taxes be raised without triggering mass protest? How tightly could imports be squeezed without precipitating a collapse in production? How far could wages be reduced without provoking labor unrest? No one could agree on the answers to such cosmic questions. What was needed was a completely new approach to the problem.
28%
Flag icon
On March 13, the French government announced that J. P. Morgan & Co. had lent it $100 million on the security of its gold reserves.
28%
Flag icon
the franc rebounded from 29 to 18 to the dollar, an appreciation of more than 60 percent in two weeks.
29%
Flag icon
Rothschilds had had an even more eventful history. The family had made its fortune during the Napoleonic Wars.
29%
Flag icon
The House of Morgan had been powerful before the war, helping to finance and restructure the steel, railway, and shipping industries; it had even bailed out the U.S. government in 1895 and saved the banking system in 1907. But its business had been largely domestic. Pierpont Morgan himself had indeed been a well-known figure in Europe, and his father, Junius Morgan, had helped the French government raise money to pay the indemnity after the Franco-Prussian war of 1870; but in international ranking, J. P. Morgan & Co. had been a second-tier house. The war had transformed its position.
29%
Flag icon
fourteen partners,
29%
Flag icon
Thomas Lamont,
29%
Flag icon
plenary
29%
Flag icon
Dawes Plan’s failure to reduce the total level of reparations was its fatal flaw. But it was Stresemann who had the final
29%
Flag icon
word. “We must get the French out of the Ruhr. We must free the Rhineland. We must accept.”
29%
Flag icon
The plan had therefore very deliberately swept a whole series of issues under the carpet.
33%
Flag icon
Though Churchill remained chancellor until 1929, by 1927 he had come to realize that the return to gold at the old prewar exchange rate had been a misjudgment. But by then there was little he could do about it except fulminate in private about the evil effects of the gold standard. In later life, he would claim that it was “the biggest blunder in his life.” He blamed it on the bad advice he had received.
33%
Flag icon
The most damaging consequence was that in a futile attempt to retain the primacy of the Bank of England and the City of London, Britain had now tied itself irretrievably to the United States.
33%
Flag icon
the Banque de France
33%
Flag icon
Banque de France
33%
Flag icon
Even after 1875, when the republic was brought into being for the third and final time
33%
Flag icon
the twelve-man Council of Regents.
33%
Flag icon
Every year at 12:30 in the afternoon, on the last Thursday of January, the pinnacle of French society would gather there for the Banque’s Annual General Assembly. Though it had more than forty thousand shareholders, only the top two hundred were eligible to attend the meeting and choose the regents.
33%
Flag icon
seated in alphabetical order would be some of the oldest and most aristocratic families in France: Clérel de Tocqueville, La Rochefoucauld, Noailles, Talleyrand-Périgord.
33%
Flag icon
With an electorate of two hundred of the richest and grandest families in France, it was not surprising that seats on the Council of Regents came to be almost hereditary. Five out of the twelve elected regents were descendants of the original founders and a disproportionately large number were Protestants of Swiss extraction.
33%
Flag icon
first convened in 1800.
33%
Flag icon
the French arm of the banking empire,
34%
Flag icon
eponymous
34%
Flag icon
Paris Commune
36%
Flag icon
Charles Rist
36%
Flag icon
History of Economic Doctrines from the Physiocrats to the Present Age,
36%
Flag icon
breaching 30 to the dollar, Rist and Quesnay began to worry that France might repeat the British mistake: an exchange rate that was too high, making exports chronically overpriced and uncompetitive.
36%
Flag icon
Every country in Europe to emerge from the war had faced the same set of issues. Britain had chosen one extreme: to impose most of the burden on its taxpayers and to protect its savers. Germany had chosen the opposite extreme: the way of pathological inflation, which had wiped away its internal debts at the price of annihilating the savings of its middle classes. Moreau was set on finding a middle way.
36%
Flag icon
he also recognized that by allowing it to rise too far, he risked driving the economy into recession.
36%
Flag icon
The principle of opposition to capping the franc’s recovery did not come from the prime minister but from within Moreau’s very own institution. A faction within the Banque’s directorate, led by the two most powerful regents, Baron Édouard de Rothschild and François de Wendel, saw in the decline of the franc the decline of France.
36%
Flag icon
No one better symbolized the power of les deux cents familles and le mur d’argent than these two men.
37%
Flag icon
On December 21, the Banque began to purchase foreign exchange and sell its own currency to prevent the franc from rising above 25 to the dollar. For the next two years, with Poincaré’s blessing, Moreau pursued a policy of intervening in the currency market to keep it pegged there.
37%
Flag icon
Unable to secure a majority within the Council of Regents, Rothschild and Wendel employed every possible tactic to undermine Moreau.
37%
Flag icon
By the middle of 1927, it was clear that Moreau had won. Waves of French capital that had fled to London or New York had washed back home, allowing the Banque to accumulate a foreign exchange war chest of $500 million dollars, most of it in pounds.
37%
Flag icon
At 25 francs to the dollar, French
37%
Flag icon
goods were among the most competitive in the world; exports were booming, while prices were stable.
37%
Flag icon
avoiding the two extremes of German-style inflation and British-style deflation.
37%
Flag icon
Whatever the reason, his decision to fix the franc at an undervalued rate would eventually help to undermine the stability of the very standard to which he had now hitched his currency.
37%
Flag icon
Circumstances rule men; men do not rule circumstances. —HERODOTUS, Histories
37%
Flag icon
No other issue would create more debate, disagreement, feuds, and confusion within the Federal Reserve System than what to do about the stock market.
37%
Flag icon
There was the erroneous notion that a rising stock market “absorbs” money from the rest of the economy. This is sheer nonsense, because for every buyer of stocks there is a seller and whatever money flows into the stock market flows immediately out.
37%
Flag icon
In the fall of 1925, Miller had also become particularly alarmed by the data on so-called brokers’ loans. These were loans provided by banks to stock brokers who used the money to finance their own inventories of securities or to lend to their own customers to buy equities on margins. Typically such margin investors only paid 20 to 25 percent of the value of stocks with their own money and borrowed the rest. The total volume of such brokers’ loans, which had averaged around $1 billion in the early years of the decade, had suddenly ballooned to $2.2 billion at the end of 1924 and looked likely ...more
38%
Flag icon
Herbert Hoover, secretary of commerce. Hoover, a Quaker orphan from Iowa, was an engineer by profession who had graduated in the very first class from Stanford and had made a fortune in the first decade of the century as a promoter of mining ventures in every corner of the globe—from China to the Transvaal, from Siberia to the Yukon, from the Malay peninsula to Tierra del Fuego. He had come to national prominence by accident as the man in charge of evacuating Americans from Europe in 1914, then as the War Food Administrator in the Wilson administration and as the head of Belgian Relief, “the ...more
38%
Flag icon
In the fall of 1925, Hoover, not shy about interfering in his cabinet colleagues’ business—Parker Gilbert called him the “Secretary of Commerce and the Under-Secretary of all other departments”—decided to launch a campaign against the pervasive atmosphere of speculation that he claimed was infecting the country, from Florida real estate to the stock market.
38%
Flag icon
For both Miller and Hoover, the culprit behind this speculative fever was Benjamin Strong. They believed that his policy of keeping interest rates artificially low to help European currencies was responsible for fueling the incipient bubble. Hoover had once been a prime supporter of American engagement in European affairs following the war, and had counted Strong a good friend. But he was now convinced that the policy of propping up Europe...
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
38%
Flag icon
Like every other financial official at the time, Strong was taken aback by the surprising strength of the stock market and was himself also worried about a potential bubble. His letters to Norman are filled with misgivings about the rise in prices on Wall Street. Though he had a somewhat jaundiced view of the stock market, dominated as it was by its motley crew of outsiders—its plungers and pool operators, all of whom were very much at the bottom of the Wall Street social ladder—he was acutely aware of its power to cause trouble. Stock market crashes and banking panics had always been closely ...more
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.
38%
Flag icon
difficult it was to identify a market bubble—to distinguish between an advance in stock prices warranted by higher profits and a rise driven purely by market psychology. Almost by definition, there were always people who believed that the market has gone too high—the stock market depended on a diversity of opinion and for every buyer dreaming of riches in 1925, there was a seller who thought the whole thing had gone too far. Strong recognized his own highly fallible judgment about stocks was a very thin reed on which to conduct the country’s monetary policy. Even though his initial reaction ...more
38%
Flag icon
wanted the Fed to focus on stabilizing the overall economy and was reluctant to allow its policies to be dominated by the need to regulate the “affairs of gamblers” who thronged the tip of Manhattan.
38%
Flag icon
In Strong’s view, something about the American character—the exuberance, the driving optimism, the naive embrace of fads—lent itself to periods of speculative excess. “It seems a shame that the best sort of plans can be handicapped by a speculative orgy,” he mused almost philosophically to Norman at the end of 1925, “and yet the temper of the people of this country is such that these situations cannot be avoided.”
38%
Flag icon
Despite the agitation from Hoover and Miller in late 1925, Strong concluded that with absolutely no signs of domestic inflation, the pound having only just returned to gold and the European currency situation still fragile, this was not the time to tighten ...
This highlight has been truncated due to consecutive passage length restrictions.