Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty
Rate it:
Open Preview
9%
Flag icon
The average citizen of the United States is seven times as prosperous as the average Mexican and more than ten times as the resident of Peru or Central America. She is about twenty times as prosperous as the average inhabitant of sub-Saharan Africa, and almost forty times as those living in the poorest African countries such as Mali, Ethiopia, and Sierra Leone.
10%
Flag icon
Ultimately the good economic institutions of the United States resulted from the political institutions that gradually emerged after 1619.
10%
Flag icon
Growth emerged slowly in the second half of the eighteenth century as the Industrial Revolution, based on major technological breakthroughs and their application in industry, took root. Industrialization in England was soon followed by industrialization in most of Western Europe and the United States. English prosperity also spread rapidly to Britain’s “settler colonies” of Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. A list of the thirty richest countries today would include them, plus Japan, Singapore, and South Korea. The prosperity of these latter three is in turn part of a broader pattern in which ...more
10%
Flag icon
If you instead make a list of the poorest thirty countries in the world today, you will find almost all of them in sub-Saharan Africa. They are joined by countries such as Afghanistan, Haiti, and Nepal, which, though not in Africa, all share something critical with African nations,
10%
Flag icon
less than $2,000 annually.
10%
Flag icon
$20,000 or more.
10%
Flag icon
So it is not just that the United States and Canada are richer than Latin America; there is also a definite and persistent divide between the rich and poor nations within Latin America.
10%
Flag icon
Without oil, Middle Eastern countries are also all poor, though, like those in Central America and the Andes, not so poor as those in sub-Saharan Africa.
10%
Flag icon
Many of these subsequently saw that growth go into reverse.
10%
Flag icon
THE GEOGRAPHY HYPOTHESIS
10%
Flag icon
One widely accepted theory of the causes of world inequality is the geography hypothesis,
10%
Flag icon
Montesquieu
11%
Flag icon
Jeffrey Sachs.
11%
Flag icon
first, that tropical diseases, particularly malaria, have very adverse consequences for health and therefore labor productivity; and second, that tropical soils do not allow for productive agriculture.
11%
Flag icon
The Aztecs had both money and writing, and the Incas, even though they lacked both these two key technologies, recorded vast amounts of information on knotted ropes called quipus.
11%
Flag icon
Disease is largely a consequence of poverty and of governments being unable or unwilling to undertake the public health measures necessary to eradicate them.
11%
Flag icon
Improved health and life expectancy were not the cause of England’s economic success but one of the fruits of its previous political and economic changes.
11%
Flag icon
it is a consequence of the ownership structure of the land and the incentives that are created for farmers by the governments and institutions under which they live. We will also show that world inequality cannot be explained by differences in agricultural productivity.
11%
Flag icon
Jared Diamond.
11%
Flag icon
the differential availability of animal and plant species created differential intensities of farming, which led to different paths of technological change and prosperity across different continents.
11%
Flag icon
This gap in incomes is closely connected to the uneven dissemination of modern industrial technologies, but this has little to do either with the potential for animal and plant domestication or with intrinsic agricultural productivity differences between Spain and Peru.
11%
Flag icon
Diamond’s thesis does not tell us why these crucial technologies are not diffusing and equalizing incomes across the world
11%
Flag icon
Inequality in the modern world largely results from the uneven dissemination and adoption of technologies,
11%
Flag icon
Yet the orientation of continents cannot provide an explanation for today’s world inequality.
11%
Flag icon
Diamond’s argument, which is about continental inequality, is not well equipped to explain variation within continents—an essential part of modern world inequality.
12%
Flag icon
But their wide distribution suggests that inequality within Eurasia cannot be explained by a theory based on the incidence of the species.
12%
Flag icon
it was the expansion and consolidation of the Ottoman Empire, and it is the institutional legacy of this empire that keeps the Middle East poor today.
12%
Flag icon
Finally, geographic factors are unhelpful for explaining not only the differences we see across various parts of the world today but also why many nations such as Japan or China stagnate for long periods and then start a rapid growth process.
12%
Flag icon
THE CULTURE HYPOTHESIS
12%
Flag icon
Max Weber,
12%
Flag icon
who argued that the Protestant Reformation and the Protestant ethic it spurred played a key role in facilitating the rise of modern industrial society in Western Europe.
12%
Flag icon
in the sense that social norms, which are related to culture, matter and can be hard to change, and they also sometimes support institutional differences, this book’s explanation for world inequality. But mostly no, because those aspects of culture often emphasized—religion, national ethics, African or Latin values—are just not important for understanding how we got here and why the inequalities in the world persist. Other aspects, such as the extent to which people trust each other or are able to cooperate, are important but they are mostly an outcome of institutions, not an independent ...more
12%
Flag icon
Yet these promising economic experiments were obliterated not by African culture or the inability of ordinary Africans to act in their own self-interest, but first by European colonialism and then by postindependence African governments.
12%
Flag icon
The real reason that the Kongolese did not adopt superior technology was because they lacked any incentives to do so.
12%
Flag icon
What about Max Weber’s Protestant ethic? Though it may be true that predominantly Protestant countries, such as the Netherlands and England, were the first economic successes of the modern era, there is little relationship between religion and economic success.
13%
Flag icon
favorite area for the enthusiasts of the culture hypothesis: the Middle East.
13%
Flag icon
religion matters?
13%
Flag icon
After Ottoman rule collapsed, the Middle East was absorbed into the English and French colonial empires,
13%
Flag icon
parts of the Middle East that temporarily broke away from the hold of the Ottoman Empire and the European powers, such as Egypt between 1805 and 1848 under Muhammad Ali, could embark on a path of rapid economic change.
13%
Flag icon
Muhammad Ali
13%
Flag icon
Nasser
13%
Flag icon
Perhaps it is the influence of English culture that is important
13%
Flag icon
The variation in prosperity within former English colonies is as great as that in the entire world.
13%
Flag icon
European versus non-European.
13%
Flag icon
In the same way, current Chinese growth has nothing to do with Chinese values or changes in Chinese culture; it results from a process of economic transformation unleashed by the reforms implemented by Deng Xiaoping and his allies,
13%
Flag icon
THE IGNORANCE HYPOTHESIS
13%
Flag icon
most economists,
13%
Flag icon
Lionel Robbins
13%
Flag icon
“economics is a science which studies human behavior as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.”
13%
Flag icon
The ignorance hypothesis maintains that poor countries are poor because they have a lot of market failures and because economists and policymakers do not know how to get rid of them